Skip to main content

Phillips Curve (New Views)

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
  • 69 Accesses

Abstract

A Phillips curve is an equation which relates the unemployment rate, or some other measure of aggregate economic activity, to a measure of the inflation rate. Since there is a significant correlation between inflation and unemployment over some horizons, understanding this correlation should yield insight into the impulses the economy faces and the mechanisms that propagate their effects. Since the 1990s, research has focused on making progress in three main areas: forecasting, microeconomic foundations and empirical tests of the microfoundations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   6,499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   8,499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Bibliography

  • Abel, A., and O. Blanchard. 1986. The present value of profits and cyclical movements in investment. Econometrica 54: 249–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkeson, A., and L.E. Ohanian. 2001. Are Phillips curves useful for forecasting inflation? Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 25(1): 2–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bakhshi, H., Kahn, H. and Rudolf, B. 2005. The Phillips curve under state-dependent pricing. Manuscript, Carleton University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bils, M., and P. Klenow. 2004. Some evidence on the importance of sticky prices. Journal of Political Economy 112: 947–985.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blinder, A., E. Canetti, D. Lebow, and J. Rudd. 1998. Asking about prices: A new approach to understanding price stickiness. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brave, S., and J.D.M. Fisher. 2004. In search of a robust inflation forecast. Economic Perspectives 28(4): 12–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G. 1983. Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics 12: 383–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, L., and T. Fitzgerald. 2003. The band pass filter. International Journal of Economics 44: 435–465.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christiano, L., M. Eichenbaum, and C. Evans. 2005. Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113: 1–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dotsey, M., R.G. King, and A.L. Wolman. 1999. State-dependent pricing and the general equilibrium dynamics of money and output. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 655–690.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichenbaum, M. and Fisher, J. 2004. Evaluating the Calvo model of sticky prices. Working Paper No. 10617. Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichenbaum, M., and J. Fisher. 2007. Estimating the frequency of price re-optimization in Calvo-style models. Journal of Monetary Economics 54(7): 2032–2047 (forthcoming).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erceg, C., J. Henderson, W. Dale, and A.T. Levin. 2000. Optimal monetary policy with staggered wage and price contracts. Journal of Monetary Economics 46: 281–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, J.D.M. 2006. The dynamic effects of neutral and investment-specific technology shocks. Journal of Political Economy 114: 413–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, J.D.M., C. Liu, and R. Zhou. 2002. When can we forecast inflation. Economic Perspectives 26(1): 30–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. 1968. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review 58: 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gagnon, E., and H. Kahn. 2005. New Phillips curve under alternative production technologies for Canada, the United States, and the Euro area. European Economic Review 49: 1571–1602.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí, J., and M. Gertler. 1999. Inflation dynamics: A structural econometric analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics 44: 195–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí, J., M. Gertler, and D. López-Salido. 2001. European inflation dynamics. European Economic Review 45: 1237–1270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí, J., M. Gertler, and D. López-Salido. 2007. Mark-ups, gaps and the welfare costs of business cycles. Review of Economics and Statistics 89: 44–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gertler, M., and J. Leahy. 2005. A Phillips curve with an Ss foundation. New York: University manuscript.

    Google Scholar 

  • Golosov, M. and Lucas, R.E., Jr. 2003. Menu costs and Phillips curves. Working Paper No. 101187. Cambridge, MA: NBER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, L.P. 1982. Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica 50: 1029–1054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimball, M. 1995. The quantitative analytics of the basic neomonetarist model. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27: 1241–1277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klenow, P. and Krystov, O. 2005. State-dependent or time-dependent pricing: Does it matter for recent US inflation? Working paper, Bank of Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1972. Expectations and the neutrality of money. Journal of Economic Theory 4: 103–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1978. Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica 46: 1429–1445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Midrigan, V. 2005. Menu costs, multiproduct firms and aggregate fluctuations. Manuscript, Ohio State University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Phillips, A.W. 1958. The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957. Economica 25: 283–299.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A., and R.M. Solow. 1960. Analytical aspects of anti-inflation policy. American Economic Review 50: 177–194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sbordone, A. 2002. Prices and unit labor costs: A new test of price stickiness. Journal of Monetary Economics 49: 265–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stahl, H. 2005. Price setting in German manufacturing: New evidence from new survey data. Working Paper No. 561, European Central Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J., and M. Watson. 1999. Forecasting inflation. Journal of Monetary Economics 44: 293–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, J. 1980. Aggregate dynamics and staggered contracts. Journal of Political Economy 88: 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. 2003. Interest and prices: Foundations of a theory of monetary policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. 2005. Firm-specific capital and the New Keynesian Phillips curve. International Journal of Central Banking 1(2): 1–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yun, T. 1996. Nominal price rigidity, money supply endogeneity, and business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 37: 345–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Copyright information

© 2018 Macmillan Publishers Ltd.

About this entry

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this entry

Fisher, J.D.M. (2018). Phillips Curve (New Views). In: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_2356

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics