The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Sequence Economies

  • Ross M. Starr
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1857

Abstract

A ‘sequence economy’ is a general equilibrium model including markets at a sequence of dates, reopening over time. It is alternative to the Arrow–Debreu model with a full set of futures markets where all exchanges for current and future goods are transacted without transaction cost at a single market date. Sequence economy markets reopen and may be incomplete (some markets, particularly futures, may be inactive) because of transaction costs. The model can provide a microeconomic general equilibrium foundation for the store-of-value function of money, since markets reopening over time create an incentive to carry money and debt intertemporally.

Keywords

Arrow–Debreu model Budget constraint Fiat money Futures markets General equilibrium Incomplete markets Infinite horizons Intertemporal transfers Overlapping generations models Sequence economies Sspot markets Store-of-value function of money Sunspot equilibrium Temporary equilibrium Transaction costs 

JEL Classifications

D5 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. Balasko, Y., and K. Shell. 1980. The overlapping-generations model, I. The case of pure exchange without money. Journal of Economic Theory 23: 281–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Balasko, Y., and K. Shell. 1981. The overlapping-generations model. II. The case of pure exchange with money. Journal of Economic Theory 24: 112–142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Chiappori, P.A., and R. Guesnerie. 1991. Sunspot equilibria in sequential markets models. In Handbook of mathematical economics, ed. W. Hildenbrand and H. Sonnenschein, vol. 4. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  4. Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of value. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  5. Geanakoplos, J. 1990. An introduction to general equilibrium with incomplete asset markets. Journal of Mathematical Economics 19: 1–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Geanakoplos, J.D., and H.M. Polemarchakis. 1991. Overlapping generations. In Handbook of mathematical economics, ed. W. Hildenbrand and H. Sonnenschein, vol. 4. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  7. Grandmont, J.M. 1977. Temporary general equilibrium theory. Econometrica 45: 535–572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Hahn, F.H. 1971. Equilibrium with transaction costs. Econometrica 39: 417–439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Heller, W.P., and R.M. Starr. 1976. Equilibrium with non-convex transactions costs: Monetary and non-monetary economies. Review of Economic Studies 43: 195–215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Hicks, J.R. 1939. Value and capital. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  11. Kurz, M. 1974. Equilibrium in a finite sequence of markets with transactions cost. Econometrica 42: 1–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Lucas, R.E. Jr. 1978. Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica 46: 1429–1445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Magill, M., and M. Quinzii. 1996. Theory of incomplete markets. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  14. Radner, R. 1972. Existence of equilibrium of plans, prices, and price expectations in a sequence of markets. Econometrica 40: 289–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Starrett, D.A. 1973. Inefficiency and the demand for ‘money’ in a sequence economy. Review of Economic Studies 40: 437–448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Wallace, N. 1980. The overlapping generations model of money. In Models of monetary economics, ed. J.H. Kareken and N. Wallace. Minneapolis: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Ross M. Starr
    • 1
  1. 1.