The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Quesnay, François (1694–1774)

  • G. Vaggi
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1734

Abstract

Quesnay was born at Mère, Seine-et-Oise. He came from a family of humble origin, the eighth of 13 children. His father Nicholas was a small merchant, and the family also had a piece of land; thanks to these two activities they were comfortably off. François Quesnay had no systematic education; at ten he could not even read, but early on he developed an interest in medicine. In 1711 he went to Paris for formal training in medicine and surgery. There he read Descartes and Malebranche, and the latter’s Recherche de la verité had a profound impact on the young Quesnay. In 1717 he married Jeanne-Cathérine Dauphin, who gave him four children, two of whom survived. He began his career at Mantes, a small town not far from Paris, and in the 1720s and 1730s he made his reputation as a surgeon, particularly with respect to bleeding techniques. In 1736 he published l’Essai physique sur l’oeconomie animale, his first major work. Quesnay was deeply involved in the polemic between surgeons and physicians which took place in the 1740s. At that time he was also physician to the Duke of Villeroy and through him and the Comtesse d’Estrades he met Madame de Pompadour, Louis XV’s favourite. Quesnay became her private physician and established himself at Versailles. In 1752 he saved the Dauphin from smallpox, and in gratitude the King granted Quesnay a noble title and a sum of money which he used to buy an estate at Beauvoir in the Minervois for his son Blaise-Guillaume. In 1750 and 1751 Quesnay published the last of his medical works and became a member of the French Académie des Sciences and of the Royal Society in London.

Keywords

Avances Baudeau, N. Capital accumulation Circulation of commodities Du Pont de Nemours, P. S. Effective demand Ephémérides du citoyen Free trade Mercier de La Rivière, P.-P. Mirabeau, Marquis de Net product Petty, W. Physiocracy Price determination Price theory Prix fundamental Quesnay, F. Single tax Sterile class Surplus Tableau économique Turgot, A. R. J. 
This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access

Bibliography

  1. Cartelier, J. 1976. Surproduit et reproduction – la formation de l’économie politique classique. Paris: Maspero.Google Scholar
  2. Daire, E. 1846. Physiocrates. Paris: Librairie de Guillaumin.Google Scholar
  3. Du Pont de Nemours, P.S. 1764. De l’importation et de l’exportation des grains. In Collection des économistes et des réformateurs sociaux de la France. Paris: Librairie Paul Geuthner, 1911.Google Scholar
  4. Eltis, W.A. 1975. François Quesnay: A reinterpretation. 2. The theory of economic growth. Oxford Economic Papers 27: 327–351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Eltis, W.A. 1984. The classical theory of economic growth. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Fox-Genovese, E. 1976. The origins of physiocracy. Economic revolution and social order in eighteenth century France. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
  7. Gilibert, G. 1977. Quesnay, la costruzione della macchina della prosperità. Milan: Etas Libri.Google Scholar
  8. Groenewegen, P.D. 1971. A re-interpretation of Turgot’s theory of capital and interest. Economic Journal 83: 327–340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Groenewegen, P.D. 1983. Quesnay. Farmers (1756) and Turgot. Sur la grande et la petite culture (1766). Reprints of Economic Classics, Series 2, No. 2. Sydney: University of Sydney.Google Scholar
  10. Hecht, J. 1958. La vie de François Quesnay. In INED (1958), vol. 1.Google Scholar
  11. Herlitz, L. 1961. The Tableau économique and the doctrine of sterility. Scandinavian Economic History Review 9 (1): 3–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. INED (Institut Nationale d’Etudes Démographiques). 1958. In François Quesnay et la Physiocratie, ed. L. Salleron, vol. 2. Paris: INED.Google Scholar
  13. Kuczynski, M., and R.L. Meek. 1972. Quesnay’s Tableau Economique. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Marx, K. 1963. Theories of surplus value. London: Lawrence & Wishart.Google Scholar
  15. Meek, R.L. 1962. The economics of physiocracy: Essays and translations. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
  16. Mirabeau, V.R. 1758–60. L’ami des hommes ou traité de la population. Reprinted Aalen: Scientia Verlag, 1970.Google Scholar
  17. Mirabeau, V.R. 1764. Philosophie rurale, ou économie générale et politique de l’agriculture. Amsterdam, chez les Libraires Associés. Reprinted Aalen: Scientia Verlag, 1972.Google Scholar
  18. Oncken, A., ed. 1888. Oeuvres économiques et philosophiques de François Quesnay. Paris: Jules Peelman.Google Scholar
  19. Petty, W. 1662. A treatise of taxes and contributions. In The economic writings of Sir William Petty, vol. 1, ed. C.H. Hull. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1899.Google Scholar
  20. Phillips, A. 1955. The Tableau Economique as a simple Leontief model. Quarterly Journal of Economics 69 (1): 137–144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Schumpeter, J.A. 1954. History of economic analysis. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
  22. Spengler, J.J. 1958. Quesnay philosophe, empiriste, économiste. In INED (1958), vol. 1.Google Scholar
  23. Tsuru, S. 1942. On reproduction schemes. In The theory of capitalist development, ed. P. Sweezy. New York: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
  24. Vaggi, G. 1987. The economics of François Quesnay. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Weulersse, G. 1910. Le mouvement physiocratique en France (de 1756 à 1770). Paris: Felix Alcan.Google Scholar
  26. Woog, H. 1950. The Tableau Economique of François Quesnay. Berne: Franckle Verlag.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • G. Vaggi
    • 1
  1. 1.