The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Joint Production in Linear Models

  • Bertram Schefold
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1210

Abstract

General joint production is defined as the simultaneous production of at least two commodities in one production process. This definition includes machines (fixed capital) that are not used up in one production period, and land which is by definition neither producible nor exhaustible.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

Bibliography

  1. Armstrong, A.G. 1975. Technology assumptions in the construction of U.K. Input–output tables. In Estimating and projecting input–output coefficients, ed. W.F. Gossling and R.I.G. Allen. London: Input–output Publishing Co.Google Scholar
  2. Baldone, S., and S. Baldone. 1974. II capitale fisso nello schema teorico di Piero Sraffa. Studi economici 29: 45–106. Trans. as ‘Fixed capital in Sraffa’s theoretical scheme’, in Pasinetti (1980).Google Scholar
  3. Chakraborty, D., T. ten Raa, and J.A. Small. 1984. An alternative treatment of secondary production in input–output analysis. Review of Economics and Statistics 66(1): 88–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Dorfman, R., P.A. Samuelson, and R. Solow. 1958. Linear programming and economic analysis. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  5. Flaschel, K.P. 1982a. On two concepts of basic commodities for joint production systems. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 42: 259–280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Flaschel, P. 1982b. Input–output technology assumptions and the energy requirements of commodities. Resources and Energy 4: 359–389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Flaschel, P. 1983. Marx Sraffa und Leontief–Kritik und Ansätze zu ihrer Synthese. Frankfurt: Peter Lang.Google Scholar
  8. Garegnani, P. 1983. The classical theory of wages and the role of demand schedules in the determination of relative prices. American Economic Review 73: 309–313.Google Scholar
  9. Gigantes, T. 1970. The representation of technology in input–output systems. In Contributions to input–output–analysis, ed. A.P. Carter and A. Brody. Amsterdam/London: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  10. Koopmans, T.C. 1951. Analysis of production as an efficient combination of activities. In Activity analysis of production and allocation: Proceedings of a conference, ed. T.C. Koopmans. New York: Yale University Press, 1976.Google Scholar
  11. Kurz, H.D. 1984. Joint production in the history of economic thought. Diskussionsbeiträge zur gesamtwirtschaftlichen Theorie und Politik. Bremen: Universität Bremen.Google Scholar
  12. Leontief, W.W. 1936. Quantitative input–output relations in the economic system of the United States. Review of Economics and Statistics 18: 105–125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Manara, C.F., and C.F. Manara. 1968. II modello di Sraffa per la produzione congiunta di merci a mezzo di merci. L’Industria 1: 3–18. Trans. as ‘Sraffa’s model of the joint production of commodities by means of commodities.’ in Pasinetti (1980), 1–15.Google Scholar
  14. Morishima, M. 1964. Equilibrium, stability and growth – A multisectoral analysis. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
  15. Nuti, D. 1973. On the truncation of production flows. Kyklos 26(3): 485–496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Pasinetti, L.L. (ed.). 1980. Essays on the theory of joint production. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  17. Salvadori, N. 1982. Existence of cost-minimizing systems within the Sraffa framework. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 42: 281–298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  18. Schefold, B. 1971. Theorie der Kuppelproduktion. PhD. Basel, privately printed.Google Scholar
  19. Schefold, B. 1974. Fixed capital as a joint product. Mimeo. Reprinted in Pasinetti (1980), 138–217.Google Scholar
  20. Schefold, B. 1978a. Multiple product techniques with properties of single product systems. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 38: 29–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Schefold, B. 1978b. On counting of equations. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 38: 253–285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Schefold, B. 1980a. Von Neumann and Sraffa: Mathematical equivalence and conceptual difference. Economic Journal 90: 140–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Schefold, B. 1980b. Fixed capital as a joint product and the analysis of accumulation with different forms of technical progress. In ed. Pasinetti (1980), 138–217.Google Scholar
  24. Schefold, B. 1985. Sraffa and applied economics. Political Economy: Studies in the Surplus Approach 1(1): 17–40.Google Scholar
  25. Sraffa, P. 1960. Production of commodities by means of commodities: Prelude to a critique of economic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  26. Steedman, I. 1976. Positive profits with negative surplus value: A reply to Mr Wolfstetter. Economic Journal 86: 873–876.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Stone, R. 1961. Input–output and national accounts. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
  28. United Nations. 1968. A system of national accounts. New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
  29. US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 1974. Definitions and conventions of the 1967 input–output study. Washington, DC.Google Scholar
  30. US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 1980. Definitions and conventions of the 1972 input–output study. Washington, DC.Google Scholar
  31. van Schaik, A.B..T.M. 1976. Reproduction and fixed capital. Rotterdam: Tilburg University Press.Google Scholar
  32. von Neumann, J. 1937. über ein ökonomisches Gleichungssystem und eine Verallgemeinerung des Brouwerschen Fixpunktsatzes. In Ergebnisse eines mathematischen Kolloquiums, vol. 8, ed. K. Menger, 73–83. Leipzig: Verlag Franz Deuticke. Trans. as ‘A model of general equilibrium’. Review of Economic Studies 13, 1945, 1–9.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • Bertram Schefold
    • 1
  1. 1.