The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

2018 Edition
| Editors: Macmillan Publishers Ltd

Insurance

  • J. J. McCall
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_1050

Abstract

Insurance is an ancient institution. It is impossible to reflect on evolutionary processes without recognizing the intrinsic role of insurance. Any species that relied on nature’s harmony and regularity and ignored its stochastic whims was soon extinct. The position adopted here is that uncertainty is one of the decisive determinants of individual behaviour. ‘Individual’ includes not only early and modern man, but also plants and animals. Furthermore, the response to uncertainty is both adaptive and dynamic. Martingale models are ideally suited to portray these responses. The goal of the individual is to maximize expected utility and for early man this was roughly equivalent to maximizing the probability of survival. In order to achieve this goal, he devised a variety of insurance mechanisms he established institutions that included a large element of flexibility so they could readily adjust to nature’s stochastic quirks. Insurance and the ensuing flexibility were key components of his decisionmaking. Aggregating these individual responses over the entire group reveals one critical aspect of the society’s culture. The individual quickly perceived that some of the most effective devices for mitigating uncertainty entailed cooperative arrangements.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access

Bibliography

  1. Arrow, K.J. 1964. The role of securities in the optimal allocation of risk-bearing. Review of Economic Studies 31, April: 91–96.Google Scholar
  2. Arrow, K.J. 1971. Essays in the theory of risk-bearing. Chicago: Markham.Google Scholar
  3. Borch, K.H. 1968. The economics of uncertainty. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  4. Bühlmann, H. 1970. Mathematical methods in risk theory. Berlin/Heidelberg/New York: Springer.Google Scholar
  5. Dubins, L., and L.J. Savage. 1965. How to gamble if you must. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  6. Ehrlich, I., and G.S. Becker. 1972, July–August. Market insurance, self-insurance, and self-protection. Journal of Political Economy 80(4): 623–648.Google Scholar
  7. Hirshleifer, J. and J.G. Riley. 1979, December. The analytics of uncertainty and information – An expository survey. Journal of Economic Literature 17(4): 1375–1421.Google Scholar
  8. Houston, A., and J. McNamara. 1985. The choice of prey types that minimizes the probability of starvation. Behavioral Ecology and Sociology 17: 135–141.Google Scholar
  9. Leadbetter, M.R., G. Lindgren, and H. Rootzen. 1983. Extremes and related properties of random sequences and processes. New York: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Liggett, T.M. 1985. Interacting particle systems. New York: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Lippman, S.A. 1972. Optimal insurance. Journal of Financial Quantitative Analysis 7: 2151–2155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Lippman, S.A., and J.J. McCall. 1980. Constant absolute risk aversion, bankruptcy, and wealth-dependent decisions. Journal of Business 53: 285–296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Lippman, S.A., and J.J. McCall. 1982. The economics of uncertainty: Selected topics and probabilistic methods. In Handbook of mathematical economics, ed. K.J. Arrow and M. Intriligator. Amsterdam/New York: North-Holland.Google Scholar
  14. Lowell, R.B. 1985. Selection for increased safety factors of biological structures as environmental unpredictability increases. Science 228: 1009–1011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. MacArthur, R.H. 1972. Geographical ecology. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Reprinted, 1984.Google Scholar
  16. Mangel, M., and D. Ludwig. 1977. Probability of extinction in a stochastic competition. SIAM Journal of Applied Mathematics 33: 256–267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Minnis, P.E. 1985. Social adaptation to food stress. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  18. Morse, D.H. 1970. Ecological aspects of some mixed species foraging flocks of birds. Ecological Monographs 40: 119–168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Nitecki, M.H. 1984. Extinctions. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  20. Pauly, M.V. 1968. The economics of moral hazard: comment. American Economic Review 58, June: 531–536.Google Scholar
  21. Pratt, J.W. 1964. Risk aversion in the small and in the large. Econometrica 32: 122–136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Radner, R. 1981. Monitoring cooperative agreements in a repeated principal-agent relationship. Econometrica 49: 1127–1148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Riley, J.G. 1975, April. Competitive signalling. Journal of Economic Theory 10(2): 174–186.Google Scholar
  24. Riley, J.G. 1979, March. Information equilibrium. Econometrica 47(2): 331–359.Google Scholar
  25. Rothschild, M., and J.E. Stiglitz. 1976, November. Equilibrium in competitive insurance markets: An essay on the economics of imperfect information. Quarterly Journal of Economics 90(4): 629–649.Google Scholar
  26. Rubinstein, A., and M.E. Yaari. 1983. Repeated insurance contracts and moral hazard. Journal of Economic Theory 30: 74–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Seal, H.L. 1969. Stochastic theory of a risk business. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
  28. Slobodkin, L.B. 1961. Growth and regulation of animal populations. New York: Holt, Rinehart & Winston.Google Scholar
  29. Spence, A.M. 1974. Market signalling: Informational transfer in hiring and related processes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  30. Zeckhauser, R. 1970, March. Medical insurance: A case study of the tradeoff between risk spreading and appropriate incentives. Journal of Economic Theory 2(1): 10–26.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Macmillan Publishers Ltd. 2018

Authors and Affiliations

  • J. J. McCall
    • 1
  1. 1.