Skip to main content

The Industrial Revolution: A Cliometric Perspective

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
Handbook of Cliometrics

Abstract

The Industrial Revolution in England represented most importantly a change in the growth rate of the efficiency of the economy from close to zero in the years before 1800 to rates typical of those for modern England or the USA by 1860. This paper details the overall change in productivity growth rates and shows also how this created an even greater increase in income per capita from induced capital accumulation. It also details the sectoral sources of this growth. Lastly, the paper considers how this fundamental economic transformation might be explained as a function of institutions, ideas, demography, and human capital investments.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The contributors here included Deane and Cole (1962), Crafts (1985), Crafts and Harley (1992), and Broadberry et al. (2014).

  2. 2.

    These estimates tend to assume large increases in agricultural output so that implied efficiency growth in agriculture is at a faster rate for the economy as a whole during the Industrial Revolution. Evidence from prices, wages, land rents, and capital returns in agriculture does not support such an optimistic assessment.

  3. 3.

    Clark (2005).

  4. 4.

    This is because a significant drag on the growth of output per person in the Industrial Revolution era was the decline in farmland per person. Since 1870, the landshare in all incomes became so modest that this drag became unimportant.

  5. 5.

    For a more detailed explanation, see Clark (2007a, pp. 379–382).

  6. 6.

    Another procedure to measure productivity growth at the sectoral level is to treat the major inputs in the same way as capital, labor, and land and measure efficiency growth as

    $$ {g}_{A_j}=-{g}_{p_j} + {a}_j{g}_{r_j} + {a}_j{p}_{kj}+{b}_j{g}_{w_j}+{c}_j{g}_{s_j} + d{g}_{m_j} $$

    where d is the share of purchased inputs in all costs and m indexes the price of such inputs. In this case,

    $$ {g}_A= {\displaystyle \sum }{\varphi}_j{g}_{Aj} $$

    where φ is the ratio of sales in each industry to national income. \( {\displaystyle \sum {\varphi}_j}>1 \) since some output is used as input into other industries and not for consumption or investment. This approach to measuring Industrial Revolution productivity advance was pioneered by McCloskey (1981).

  7. 7.

    Bresnahan and Trajtenberg (1996).

  8. 8.

    Clark and Jacks (2007).

  9. 9.

    By 1828, three-quarters of mines in the Newcastle area were still less than 600 f. deep. Clark and Jacks (2007, Table 2).

  10. 10.

    Wrigley (1988), Pomeranz (2000).

  11. 11.

    Vries (2001).

  12. 12.

    For more details, see Clark and Jacks (2007).

  13. 13.

    Wicker (1957).

  14. 14.

    Overton (1985, Table 1).

  15. 15.

    Overton (1991, pp. 309–310).

  16. 16.

    Clark (1998), Clark and Jamelske (2005).

  17. 17.

    This is also the analysis of Mokyr (2003, 2012).

  18. 18.

    Aglionby (1669, pp. 3–4).

  19. 19.

    The discussion below is largely based on De Vries and Van der Woude (1997), though see also Freist (2012) and de Vries (2000).

  20. 20.

    De Vries and Van der Woude (1997, p. 710).

  21. 21.

    By 1665 the State of Holland was able to reduce rates on its long term debt to 4 %.

  22. 22.

    De Vries (1978).

  23. 23.

    See Eq. 3 above.

  24. 24.

    Allen (2009).

  25. 25.

    Clark (1996, 2007a, b) criticizes this approach.

  26. 26.

    The recent rise of China is, however, an exception to the general association of growth and democracy.

  27. 27.

    The Dutch Act of Abjuration of 1581 has been claimed by some to be the precursor of the Declaration of Independence of the USA of 1776.

  28. 28.

    See Prak (1997), van Zanden and Prak (2006, pp. 121–122).

  29. 29.

    There have been institutionalist arguments, however, about why Hansa institutions still deviated from those necessary for modern growth. See Lindberg (2009).

  30. 30.

    This problem continued into at least the seventeenth century in England, where publishers quite freely pirated the works of authors.

  31. 31.

    See Long (1991, pp. 853–857).

  32. 32.

    Ganea and Pattloch (2005, pp. 205–206).

  33. 33.

    De Vries and van der Woude (1997, pp. 345–348).

  34. 34.

    Khan (2008).

  35. 35.

    The industrialization of the United States created much greater private and family fortunes.

  36. 36.

    Jacob (2013, p. 8).

  37. 37.

    Mokyr (1999).

  38. 38.

    Jacob (2014, pp. 82–84). See also Jacob (1997).

  39. 39.

    Shineberg (1971, p. 65).

  40. 40.

    Townsend (1983, p. 6).

  41. 41.

    Wrigley et al. (1997, p. 313).

  42. 42.

    Hopkins (1966, p. 249).

  43. 43.

    France was the only country to experience a decline in fertility starting in the late eighteenth century, and France of course lagged Britain in terms of the onset of modern growth.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA (2012) Why nations fail: the origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. Crown Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA, Johnson S (2001) The colonial origins of comparative economic development: an empirical investigation. Am Econ Rev 91:1369–1401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Robinson JA, Johnson S (2002) Reversal of fortune: geography and institutions in the making of the modern world. Q J Econ 117:1231–1294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson JA (2005) The rise of Europe: Atlantic trade, institutional change and economic growth. Am Econ Rev 95:546–579

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aglionby W (1669) The present state of the United Provinces of the Low-Countries as the government, laws, forces, riches, manners, customes, revenue, and territory of the Dutch in three books: collected by W.A. Fellow of the Royal Society, London 1669. http://gateway.proquest.com/openurl?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2003&res_id=xri:eebo&rft_id=xri:eebo:image:64416

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen RC (2009) The British industrial revolution in global perspective. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boberg-Fazlic N, Sharp P, Weisdorf J (2011) Survival of the richest? Testing the Clark hypothesis using English pre-industrial data from family reconstitution records. Eur Rev Econ Hist 15(3):365–392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bresnahan TF, Trajtenberg M (1996) General purpose technologies: engines of growth? J Econ Ann Econ 65:83–108

    Google Scholar 

  • Broadberry S, Campbell B, Klein A, Overton M, van Leeuwen B (2014) British economic growth, 1270–1870. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (1996) The political foundations of modern economic growth: England, 1540–1800. J Interdiscip Hist 26:563–588

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (1998) Commons sense: common property rights, efficiency, and institutional change. J Econ Hist 58(1):73–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2005) The condition of the working-class in England, 1209–2004. J Polit Econ 113(6):1307–1340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2007a) A farewell to alms: a brief economic history of the world. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2007b) A review of Avner Greif’s, institutions, and the path to the modern economy. J Econ Lit 45:727–743

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G (2010) The macroeconomic aggregates for England, 1209–2008. Res Econ Hist 27:51–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G, Cummins N. (2015) Malthus to modernity: wealth, status, and fertility in England, 1500–1879. J Popul Econ: 3–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark G, Cummins N (2014) The child quality-quantity tradeoff and the industrial revolution. Working paper, University of California, Davis

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark G, Jacks D (2007) Coal and the industrial revolution, 1700–1869. Eur Rev Econ Hist 11(1):39–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G, Jamelske E (2005) The efficiency gains from site value taxes: the Tithe Commutation Act of 1836. Explor Econ Hist 42(2):282–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark G, Levin P (2001) How different was the industrial revolution? The revolution in printing, 1350–1869. Working paper, University of California, Davis

    Google Scholar 

  • Crafts NFR (1985) British economic growth during the industrial revolution. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Crafts NFR, Harley CK (1992) Output growth and the industrial revolution: a restatement of the Crafts-Harley view. Econ Hist Rev 45:703–730

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Vries J (1978) Barges and capitalism: passenger transportation in the Dutch Economy, 1632–1839. A.A.G. Bijdragen no. 21. Wageningen

    Google Scholar 

  • De Vries J (2000) Dutch economic growth in comparative historical perspective, 1500–2000. De Economist 148:443–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Vries J, van der Woude AM (1997) The first modern economy. Success, failure, and perseverance of the Dutch economy from 1500 to 1815. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Deane P, Cole WA (1962) British economic growth 1688–1959. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • DeLong BJ, Shleifer A (1993) Princes and merchants: European city growth before the industrial revolution. J Law Econ 36:671–702

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duncan-Jones R (1990) Structure and scale in the roman economy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Freist D (2012) The “Dutch Century.” In: European History Online (EGO). Leibniz Institute of European History (IEG), Mainz

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor O (2011) Unified growth theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Weil DN (2000) Population, technology and growth: from malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. Am Econ Rev 90:806–828

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ganea P, Pattloch T (2005) Intellectual property law in China, vol 11, Max Planck series on Asian intellectual property law. Kluwer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif A (2006) Institutions and the path to the modern economy: lessons from medieval trade. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Harley CK (1998) Cotton textile prices and the industrial revolution. Econ Hist Rev 51(1):49–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harley CK (2010) Prices and profits in cotton textiles during the industrial revolution. University of Oxford discussion papers in economic history, #81

    Google Scholar 

  • Hopkins K (1966) On the probable age structure of the Roman population. Popul Stud 20(2):245–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacob M (1997) Scientific culture and the making of the industrial West. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacob M (2013) How to think about culture in relation to economic development. Working paper, LSE

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacob M (2014) The first knowledge economy: human capital and the European economy, 1750–1850. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Khan Z (2008) An economic history of patent institutions. In: Whaples R (ed) EH.Net encyclopedia. http://eh.net/encyclopedia/an-economic-history-of-patent-institutions/

  • Lindberg E (2009) Club goods and inefficient institutions: why Danzig and Lübeck failed in the early modern period. Econ Hist Rev N Ser 62(3):604–628

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Long P (1991) Invention, authorship, ‘intellectual property’, and the origin of patents: notes towards a conceptual history. Technol Cult 32:846–884

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. J Monet Econ 22:3–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malthus TR (1798) An essay on the principle of population. J. Johnson, London

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey DN (1981) The industrial revolution: 1780–1860, a survey. In: Floud R, McCloskey D (eds) The economic history of Britain since 1700. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 103–128

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill J (1821) Elements of political economy. Baldwin, Cradock and Joy, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell BR (1988) British historical statistics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell BR, Deane P (1971) Abstract of British historical statistics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J (1999) The industrial revolution and the Netherlands: why did it not happen? Prepared for the 150th Anniversary conference organized by the Royal Dutch Economic Association, Amsterdam, 1999

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J (2003) Long-term economic growth and the history of technology. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J (2012) The enlightened economy. An economic history of Britain 1700–1850. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1981) Structure and change in economic history. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1994) Economic performance through time. Am Econ Rev 84(3):359–368

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC, Thomas RP (1973) The rise of the western world. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North DC, Weingast BR (1989) Constitutions and commitment: evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth century England. J Econ Hist 49:803–832

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North DC, Wallis JJ, Weingast BR (2012) Violence and social orders: a conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Overton M (1985) The diffusion of agricultural innovations in early modern England: turnips and clover in Norfolk and Suffolk, 1580–1740. Trans Inst Br Geogr N Ser 10(2):205–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Overton M (1991) The determinants of crop yields in early modem England. In: Campbell BMS, Overton M (eds) Land, labour and livestock. Manchester University Press, Manchester, pp 284–322

    Google Scholar 

  • Pomeranz K (2000) The great divergence: China, Europe and the making of the modern world economy. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Prak M (1997) Burghers, citizens and popular politics in the Dutch Republic. Eighteenth Century Stud 30(4):443–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reis J (2005) Economic growth, human capital formation and consumption in Western Europe before 1800. In: Allen RC, Tommy B, Martin D (eds) Living standards in the past: new perspectives on well-being in Asia and Europe. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 195–226

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo D (1821) On the principals of political economy and taxation, 3rd edn. John Murray, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. J Polit Econ 94:1002–1037

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal J-L (1992) The fruits of revolution, property rights, litigation and French agriculture (1700–1860). Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein WD (1981) Men of property: the very wealthy in Britain since the industrial revolution. Croom Helm, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Shineberg D (1971) Guns and men in Melanesia. J Pac Hist 6:61–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1776) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. W. Strahan and T. Cadell, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Townsend JB (1983) Firearms against native arms: a study in comparative efficiencies with an Alaskan example. Arct Anthropol 20(2):1–33

    Google Scholar 

  • van Zanden JL (2008) Prices and wages and the cost of living in the western part of the Netherlands, 1450–1800. Working paper, International Institute of Social History, Amsterdam. http://www.iisg.nl/hpw/brenv.php

  • van Zanden JL, Prak M (2006) Towards an economic interpretation of citizenship: the Dutch Republic between medievalcommunes and modern nation-states. Eur Rev Econ Hist 10(2):111–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vries PHH (2001) Are coal and colonies really crucial? Kenneth Pomeranz and the Great Divergence. J World Hist 12(2):407–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wicker ER (1957) A note on Jethro Tull: innovator or crank? Agric Hist 31(1):46–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley EA (1988) Continuity, chance and change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley EA, Davies RS, Oeppen JE, Schofield RS (1997) English population history from family reconstruction: 1580–1837. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge/New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gregory Clark .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this entry

Cite this entry

Clark, G. (2016). The Industrial Revolution: A Cliometric Perspective. In: Diebolt, C., Haupert, M. (eds) Handbook of Cliometrics. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-40406-1_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics