Keywords

Introduction

A myriad of climate change adaptation policies have been proposed to improve farmers and herdsmen’s resilience building capacity, diversify their income and food, and increase their welfare in a changing climate. Several computation methods have been used to analyze discrete choice and best-worst datasets. While conditional logit, multinomial logit have been widely used in the academic literature, the usage of mixed logit (ML) models has been exploded because it is capable to relax (IIA) and can approximate any random utility model (McFadden and Train 2000).

A recent research has studied mixed logit models: accuracy and software choice by comparing ML across three popular packages, namely, SAS, NLOGIT-LIMDEP, and a user-written add-in module for STATA. Results indicate that the data generating process used was not well suited to evaluate the accuracy of software packages and further research is needed to determine which software is the most accurate (Chang and Lusk 2011).

Another challenge is to determine the climate change adaptation policy, and there are few studies geared at computing welfare effects of individual climate change policy. In addition, determining the relative importance of several climate change policy options can be challenging though they may have the same objective towards resilience building. For instance, prolific animal selection and changing herd composition both aim at reducing herd size and thereby enhancing agropastoralists’ resilience build capacity. A third challenge facing researcher is to write an algorithm capable of solving real-life problem.

This chapter contributes to fill a knowledge gap by eliciting agropastoralists preference for alternative climate change policies and also enriching literature related to climate change and choice modeling. While data collected from choice experiment and best-worst have been well-documented, coding methods and algorithm development vary considerably from one statistical package to another.

Background on BWS

Climate change is increasingly becoming recognized as a global threat and concerted effort such as new climate change adaptation strategies should be undertaken both at local, national, and regional and global levels.

While various government climate change adaptation policies have been proposed to reinforce vulnerable farmers’ resilience capacity, little is relatively known about farmers indigenous knowledge related to climate change adaptation strategies. However, not all climate change policies have had expected results on farmers’ welfare, and previous studies have indicated that combined government and farmers adaptation strategies are more welfare enhancing (Tabbo et al. 2016).

Climate Change Policy Identification and Survey Design

Based on previous research and interview with agropastoralists, 13 climate change adaptation policies have been identified and included in this study. To determine the relative importance that agropastoralists place on these policies, a BWS experiment was designed (Marley and Louvriere 2005). A balanced incomplete block design (BIBD) developed by Louviere et al. (2015) has been used to determine allocation of the 13 policies for each BW question. The resulted design contains 13 BWS questions, each having four policy options. The BIBD is the most widely used design in the BWS literature because it is not only a balanced design but also an orthogonal design (Flynn and Marley 2014). Furthermore, the policies were selected to reflect the main issues and challenges recently discussed in climate change adaptation choice as compared to the food choice literature documented by Lusk and McCluskey (2018).

For each BWS question, respondent was asked to select his best and his worst climate change adaptation policies. Figure 1 listed below reports an example of the best-worst questions used in the study.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Please select your best and worst endogenous strategies

The coding method used for R is based on position for each pair of best-worst question. The value for the position can be ranged from 1 to 4. For SAS, best options will be assigned 1, worst options (-1), and 0 for non-chosen options. This shows that a scale difference may exist between the two coding methods (Table 1).

Table 1 Climate change adaptation policy and description

Data Analysis

The BWS approach assumes that respondents simultaneously make repeated choices by choosing the best and worst items in a given set and thereby maximizing the difference (Flynn and Marley 2014). By denoting J as number of items in each BWS question (4 climate change adaptation policies), then J (J−1) best-worst pairs of best-worst choices are possible.

By following this approach, our data were analyzed using random utility framework which is well rooted in microeconomics (McFadden 1974), whereby a given respondent n derives from the selected best-worst pairs in each BWS question t is the difference in utility between the j best and k worst policies.

This can be mathematically expressed:

$$ {U}_{njt}={\mu}_{jt}-{\mu}_{kt}+{\varepsilon}_{njt} $$
(1)

where μ is the vector of estimated importance parameters of the best and worst climate change policies (j and k respectively) relative to some policy normalized to zero for identification.

The probability that respondents choose item j as best and k as worst out of J items in BWS question t is the probability that the difference in utility of the chosen items (Unjt and Unkt) is greater than all other J (J−1)−1 possible differences within each BWS question (Lusk and Briggeman 2009). While several econometric methods can be used to model this behavior, mixed logit is the most widely used estimation procedure, because it is flexible and can approximate any random utility model (Train 2009).

The mixed logit model and the probability that an individual n chooses j as best and k as worst can be mathematically written as follows:

$$ {P}_{nj}=\int \mu {\prod}_{t=1}^T\frac{e^{\left[{\mu}_{nj t}-{\mu}_{nkt}\right]}}{\sum_{l=1}^J{\sum}_{m=1}^J{e}^{\left[{\mu}_{nlt}-{\mu}_{nmt}\right]-J}}f\left({\mu}_n\right)d{\mu}_n $$
(2)

where f(μn) is the density of the importance parameters μn.

The share of preferences for each climate change adaptation policy can be expressed as follows:

$$ {\varphi}_j=\frac{e^{\mu_j}}{\sum_{k=1}^j{e}^{\mu_k}} $$
(3)

where φj is the share of preference for a given climate change adaptation policy.

Results

Data were collected via well-structured questionnaire delivered to a sample of 271 respondents. Summary statistics and variable definitions are reported in Table 2. Most of the respondents have an average of 40 years and about 76% of respondents were male and 84% of the respondents were married. About 75% of respondents were uneducated, and about 52% and 27% of our sample have an annual income below 90,000 FCFA and between 90,0000 and 180,000 FCFA, respectively. In addition, average household size was 8 persons with an average of 16 and 24 respectively for large animal and small animal. About 87% of respondents strongly believe that climate change and environment are correlated.

Table 2 Characteristics of surveyed respondents

Table 3 reports estimates from mixed logit models for both R and SAS software. Coefficients reflect the importance of each 12 climate change adaptation polices to forage cultivation, which was normalized to zero for identification purpose. Results show that based on R software estimation, strategic mobility followed by mutual assistance, settlement, strategic destocking, prolific animal selection, sheep and cattle fattening, vaccination, transhumance, emergency destocking, water and soil conservation activities, and changing herd composition are the most climate change adaptation policies with a significant difference to forage cultivation. Standard deviation estimates for 12 climate change adaptation policies obtained from R software were statistically and highly significant, implying that heterogeneity is a pattern when analyzing climate policies within the population. Table 2 also reports SAS software estimates. Results reveal that settlement followed by emergency destocking, prolific animal selection, water and soil conservation activities, strategic mobility, transhumance, and mutual assistance are the most important climate change adaptation polices relative to forage cultivation. Results also suggest that standard deviation estimates for settlement, emergency destocking, prolific animal selection, water and soil conservation activities, strategic mobility, transhumance, mutual assistance, sheep and cattle fattening, and changing herd composition are statistically significant, revealing that these estimates do vary in the population and thereby confirming heterogeneity pattern. Heterogeneity pattern when analyzing data in R is higher than heterogeneity pattern with SAS.

Table 3 Mixed logit models for best-worst scaling data: software and coding method accuracies

Table 3 also shows that R and SAS generated different mean estimates. For instance, the mean estimates for strategic mobility were 0.887 and 0.264 respectively for R and SAS. Similarly, the mean estimates for mutual assistance were 0.587 and 0.172 respectively for R and SAS. The mean estimates for settlement were 0.582 and 0.571 respectively for R and SAS. The mean estimates generated by R are all statistically significant. Similarly, the standard error estimates for strategic mobility, mutual assistance are higher for R than SAS, while standard error estimates for settlement and prolific animal selection are higher for SAS than R. This implies that estimates of standard errors considerably diverge across R and SAS. The standard deviation estimates are generally higher and significant for R than SAS; implying heterogeneity pattern is highly significant for R than SAS. Consequently, R software accurately predicted heterogeneity pattern than SAS.

Table 4 reports share of preferences for R and SAS software estimates. Results show that 12.17%, 9.02%, and 8.97% of respondents viewed strategic mobility, mutual assistance, and settlement as the most desirable climate change adaptation policies, respectively. Based on SAS estimates, 11.63%, 9.51%, and 9.30% of respondents viewed settlement, emergency destocking, and prolific animal selection as the most desirable climate change adaptation policies, respectively. This indicates that share of preference for settlement estimated with SAS is higher than estimate from R. Conversely, share of preference for strategic mobility estimated with R is higher than estimate from SAS. Share of preference for mutual assistance under R is higher than that of SAS. This shows that mixed results prevail while estimating share of preferences under R and SAS. Results also indicate that SAS’s algorithm converges faster than that of R.

Table 4 Share of preferences based on R and SAS estimates

Table 5 reports the intention to vote for or against each climate change adaptation policy. Results based on R estimation show that more than 70% of respondents would vote for the implementation of policies such as prolific animal selection (100%), vaccination (100%), settlement (84%), strategic mobility (77%), strategic destocking, and sheep and cattle fattening (74%). Forage cultivation (50%) and income generating activities (52%) had the lowest vote share among respondents. Results based on SAS estimates indicate that more than 70% of respondents would vote the implementation of policies such as income generating activities (88%), water and soil conservation activities (82%), and settlement and strategic mobility (70%). Strategic destocking (26%) and changing herd composition (27%) had the lowest vote share among respondents. Results from Tables 3 and 4 further suggest that concordance between preferences for climate change adaptation polices and voting behavior does exist. Voting implementation results reveal that R and SAS estimates greatly vary.

Table 5 Agropastoral’s vote for climate change adaptation policy implementation

Conclusion

A mosaic of climate change adaptation policies have been proposed to build rural household resilience capacity and diversify income and food strategies and improve their livelihood.

This chapter uses BWS approach to elicit Niger agropastoralists preferences for climate change adaptation policies. Using data collected from 271 agropastoralists, results indicate that agropastoralists have a clear preference for settlement, emergency destocking, prolific animal selection, water and soil conservation activities, strategic mobility, transhumance, and mutual assistance. While results also suggest that mean, standard error and standard deviation estimates of these preferences vary across R and SAS package, R package yielded more accurate results than SAS.

Results further suggest that share of preferences and vote for climate change adaptation policy implementation are software package dependent. Future research is to study the stability of climate change adaptation policies overtime. Lusk (2012) stated that public policy is highly interventionist and that policy preferences are more likely to change external shocks when climate change hit, food safety crisis occurred, and negative externalities happened.