Skip to main content

Analytical Bounds for Treasury Bond Futures Prices

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
Handbook of Financial Econometrics and Statistics
  • 9220 Accesses

Abstract

The pricing of delivery options, particularly timing options, in Treasury bond futures is prohibitively expensive. Recursive use of the lattice model is unavoidable for valuing such options, as Boyle (1989) demonstrates. As a result, the main purpose of this study is to derive upper bounds and lower bounds for Treasury bond futures prices.

This study employs a maximum likelihood estimation technique presented by Chen and Scott (1993) to estimate the parameters for two-factor Cox-Ingersoll-Ross models of the term structure. Following the estimation, the factor values are solved for by matching the short rate with the cheapest-to-deliver bond price. Then, upper bounds and lower bounds for Treasury bond futures prices can be calculated.

This study first shows that the popular preference-free, closed-form cost of carry model is an upper bound for the Treasury bond futures price. Then, the next step is to derive analytical lower bounds for the futures price under one- and two-factor Cox-Ingersoll-Ross models of the term structure. The bound under the two-factor Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model is then tested empirically using weekly futures prices from January 1987 to December 2000.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 849.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See, for example, Carr and Chen (1996), Kilcollin (1982), Benninga and Smirlock (1985), Kane and Marcus (1986), and Hedge (1990).

  2. 2.

    See, for example, Arak and Goodman (1987), Hedge (1988), and Gay and Manaster (1986).

  3. 3.

    These bounds are not to be violated, or arbitrage profits should take place. As it will become clear (in Sect. 71.4), in the case of the upper bound that is model-free, a simple trading strategy can be formed to arbitrage against the violation (under perfect markets). In the case of the semi-model-dependent lower bound, arbitrage profits exist only if the assumed model is correct.

  4. 4.

    T bond market is an over the counter market that has no official closing time, even though market practice adopts 3:00 p.m. Eastern time as a symbolic closing time. The futures market allows the short up to 8:00 p.m. Eastern time to make the delivery announcement, and hence theoretically there is a 5-h window for the wild card.

  5. 5.

    Also see Hull (2009).

  6. 6.

    For example, the closed-form solution under the one-factor Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model can be found in Carr (1988).

  7. 7.

    The name “accrued interest” comes in because in the delivery month, the bond price increases due to accrued interests. Here, Q is a traded price that included accrued interests.

  8. 8.

    If there is a coupon in between t and T, we simply subtract the coupon value from the expected value.

  9. 9.

    Note that in the second line of Eq. 71.17 where q i is divided through is due to the fact that there exists a bond i such that max{Φ(u)q i δ(t, u + h)Q i (u + h)} > 0 in all states.

  10. 10.

    This two-factor model is adopted by a number of authors. See Chen and Scott (1993), Turnbull and Milne (1991), Langetieg (1980), and Hull and White (1990).

  11. 11.

    T bond futures prices are affected by all bonds underlying the yield curve, and yet doubtlessly the cheapest-to-deliver bond has the most influence.

  12. 12.

    See, for example, Chen and Scott (1993) and Jagannathan et al. (2003).

  13. 13.

    All 10 cases are in the second subperiod: 1992–2000.

  14. 14.

    Chen and Scott (1993) argue that the three-factor model does not necessarily dominate the two-factor model; in that, the three-factor model, although fits better the term structure, generates extra volatility. See Chen and Scott for details.

  15. 15.

    The result of the alternative fitting is available upon request.

  16. 16.

    Hull (2009) has an excellent demonstration of such a computation.

  17. 17.

    That is, we do the business day count between trade day and the last day of the delivery month and assume 252 trading days for a given year.

  18. 18.

    Lee et al. (2000) provide excellent introductions about how to conduct multiple regressions.

References

  • Arak, M., & Goodman, L. (1987). Treasury bond futures: Valuing the delivery option. Journal of Futures Markets, 7(3), 269–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benninga, S., & Smirlock, M. (1985). An empirical analysis of the delivery option, marking to market, and the pricing of Treasury bond futures. Journal of Futures Markets, 5(3), 361–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyle, P. (1989). The quality option and timing option in futures contracts. Journal of Finance, 44(1), 101–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadie, M., & Sundaresan, S. (1987) The pricing of timing and quality options: An application to Treasury bond futures markets. Working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carr, P. (1988) Valuing bond futures and the quality option. Working paper, University of California at Los Angeles.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carr, P., & Chen, R. (1996). Valuing bond futures and the quality option. Working paper, Rutgers University, November.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, R., & Scott, L. (1993). Maximum likelihood estimation of a multi-factor equilibrium model of the term structure of interest rates. Journal of Fixed Income, 3(3), 14–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, R., & Yeh, S. K. (2002). Analytical bounds for American option prices. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 37(01), 117–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J., Ingersoll, J., & Ross, S. (1981). The relation between forward prices and futures prices. Journal of Financial Economics, 9(4), 321–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J., Ingersoll, J., & Ross, S. (1985). A theory of the term structure of interest rates. Econometrica, 53(2), 385–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duan, J., & Simonato, J. (1999). Estimating and testing exponential-affine term structure models by Kalman Filter. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 13, 111–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gay, G., & Manaster, S. (1986). Implicit delivery options and optimal delivery strategies for financial futures contracts. Journal of Financial Economics, 16(1), 41–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamiltion, J. (1994). Time series analysis. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heath, D., Jarrow, R., & Morton, A. (1992). Bond pricing and the term structure of interest rates: A new methodology for contingent claims valuation. Econometrica, 60(1), 77–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hedge, S. (1988). An empirical analysis of implicit delivery options in the Treasury bond futures contract. Journal of Banking and Finance, 12(2), 469–492.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hedge, S. (1990). An ex post valuation of the quality option in Treasury bond futures contract. Journal of Banking and Finance, 14(4), 741–760.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hemler, M. (1990). The quality delivery option in Treasury bond futures contracts. Journal of Finance, 45(5), 1565–1586.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T., Lee, S., & Son, K. (1992). Term structure estimation and pricing of callable Treasury bonds. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 2(2), 127–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hull, J. (2009) Options, futures, and other derivative contracts (7th ed.) Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hull, J., & White, A. (1990). Pricing interest-rate-derivative securities. The Review of Financial Studies, 3(4), 573–592.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jagannathan, R., Kaplin, A., & Sun, S. (2003). An evaluation of multi-factor CIR models using LIBOR, swap rates, and cap and swaption prices. Journal of Econometrics, 116, 113–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jamshidian, F. (1989). An exact bond option formula. Journal of Finance, 4(1), 205–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kane, A., & Marcus, A. (1984). Conversion factor risk and hedging in the Treasury bond futures market. Journal of Futures Markets, 4(1), 55–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kane, A., & Marcus, A. (1986). Valuation and optimal exercise of the wild card option in the Treasury bond futures market. Journal of Finance, 41(1), 195–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilcollin, T. (1982). Difference systems in financial futures markets. Journal of Finance, 37(5), 1883–1897.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langetieg, T. (1980). A multivariate model of the term structure. Journal of Finance, 35(1), 71–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee C., Lee A., & Lee J. (2000). Statistics for business and financial economics (2nd ed). World Scientific Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Livingston, M. (1987). The delivery option on forward contracts. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 22(01), 79–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lo, A. W. (1987). Semi-parametric upper bounds for options prices and expected payoffs. Journal of Financial Economics, 19(2), 373–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Longstaff, F., & Schwartz, E. (1992). Interest rate volatility and the term structure: A two-factor general equilibrium model. Journal of Finance, 47(4), 1259–1282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Margrabe, W. (1978). The value of an option to exchange one asset for another. Journal of Finance, 33, 177–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritchken, P., & Sankarasubramanian, L. (1992). Pricing the quality option in Treasury bond futures. Mathematical Finance, 2(3), 197–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, S., & Milne, F. (1991). A simple approach to interest-rate option pricing. The Review of Financial Studies, 4(1), 87–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vasicek, O. (1977). An equilibrium characterization of the term structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 5(2), 177–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yeh, S. K., & Lin, B. H. (2003). Term structure fitting and information content: An empirical study on the Taiwanese government bond market. Review of Pacific Basin Financial Markets and Policies, 6(3), 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, P. G. (1994). Bounds for option prices and expected payoffs. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 4(2), 179–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ren-Raw Chen .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

From Theorem 1, we have:

$$ \begin{array}{c}{E}_t^Q\left[\delta \left(t,T\right)X(T)\right]={E}_t^Q\left[\delta \left(t,T\right)\right]{E}_t^{F(T)}\left[X(T)\right]\\ {}=P\left(t,T\right){E}_t^{F(T)}\left[X(T)\right]\end{array} $$
(71.37)

where δ is strictly less than 1. Due to the risk-neutral pricing result we have, the LHS must equal X(t), and hence:

$$ X(t)=\frac{E_t^{F(T)}\left[X(T)\right]}{P\left(t,T\right)} $$
(71.38)

Note that the forward measure is maturity dependent. Clearly, the Radon-Nikodym derivative (RND) is

$$ \eta \left(t,T\right)=\frac{\delta \left(t,T\right)}{P\left(t,T\right)} $$
(71.39)

Since the measure is T-dependent, so should be the RND (usually, RND is just η(t)). Let the interest rate process be

$$ dr(t)=\widehat{\mu}\left(r,t\right) dt+\sigma \left(r,t\right)d{W}^Q(t) $$
(71.40)

Applying Ito’s lemma,

$$ \begin{array}{c}0= \ln \kern0.5em P\left(T,T\right)= \ln \kern0.2em P\left(t,T\right)+{\displaystyle {\int}_t^T\frac{1}{P\left(u,T\right)}}{P}_u\left(u,T\right) du+{P}_r\left(u,T\right) dr+\frac{1}{2}{P}_{rr}\left(u,T\right){(dr)}^2d\widehat{W}(u)-{\displaystyle {\int}_t^T}\frac{1}{2}{\left[\frac{\sigma \left(r,u\right){P}_r\left(u,T\right)}{P\left(u,T\right)}\right]}^2 du\\ {}= \ln \kern0.5em P\left(t,T\right)+{\displaystyle {\int}_t^T\frac{1}{P\left(u,T\right)}}\left[{P}_u\left(u,T\right) du+{P}_r\left(u,T\right)\widehat{\mu}\left(r,u\right)+\frac{1}{2}{P}_{rr}\left(u,T\right)\sigma {\left(r,u\right)}^2\right] du\\ {}+{\displaystyle {\int}_t^T}\frac{1}{P\left(u,T\right)}{P}_r\left(u,T\right)\sigma \left(r,u\right)d\widehat{W}(u)-{\displaystyle {\int}_t^T\frac{1}{2}{\left[\frac{\sigma \left(r,u\right){P}_r\left(u,T\right)}{P\left(u,T\right)}\right]}^2 du}= \ln \kern0.5em P\left(t,T\right)+{\displaystyle {\int}_t^Tr(u) du}+{\displaystyle {\int}_t^T\frac{1}{P\left(u,T\right)}}{P}_r\left(u,T\right)\sigma \left(r,u\right)d\widehat{W}(u)-{\displaystyle {\int}_t^T\frac{1}{2}}{\left[\frac{\sigma \left(r,u\right){P}_r\left(u,T\right)}{P\left(u,T\right)}\right]}^2 du\end{array} $$
(71.41)

Letting:

$$ \theta \left(t,T\right)=-\frac{\sigma \left(r,t\right){P}_r\left(t,T\right)}{P\left(t,T\right)} $$
(71.42)

and moving the first two terms to the left:

$$ \begin{array}{l}-{\displaystyle {\int}_t^Tr(u) du}- \ln \kern0.5em P\left(t,T\right)={\displaystyle {\int}_t^T-\theta \left(u,T\right)d\widehat{W}(u)}-{\displaystyle {\int}_t^T\frac{1}{2}}\theta {\left(u,T\right)}^2 du\\ {}\frac{\delta \left(t,T\right)}{P\left(t,T\right)}=\eta \left(t,T\right)= \exp \left({\displaystyle {\int}_t^T-}\theta \left(u,T\right)d\widehat{W}(u)-{\displaystyle {\int}_t^T\frac{1}{2}}\theta {\left(u,T\right)}^2 du\right)\end{array} $$
(71.43)

This implies the Girsanov transformation of the following:

$$ \begin{array}{c}{W}^{F(T)}(t)={W}^Q(t)+{\displaystyle {\int}_t^T\theta (u) dt}\\ {}={W}^Q(t)-{\displaystyle {\int}_t^T\sigma \left(r,u\right)}\frac{P_r\left(u,T\right)}{P\left(u,T\right)} du\end{array} $$
(71.44)

The interest rate process under the forward measure henceforth becomes:

$$ dr(t)=\left[\widehat{\mu}\left(r,t\right)+\sigma {\left(r,t\right)}^2\frac{P_r\left(t,T\right)}{P\left(t,T\right)}\right] dt+\sigma \left(r,t\right)d{W}^{F(T)}(t) $$
(71.45)

Note that the forward measure is quite general. It does not depend on any specific assumption on the interest rate process.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this entry

Cite this entry

Chen, RR., Yeh, SK. (2015). Analytical Bounds for Treasury Bond Futures Prices. In: Lee, CF., Lee, J. (eds) Handbook of Financial Econometrics and Statistics. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-7750-1_71

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-7750-1_71

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, New York, NY

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-4614-7749-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4614-7750-1

  • eBook Packages: Business and Economics

Publish with us

Policies and ethics