Skip to main content

The Intertemporal Relation Between Expected Return and Risk on Currency

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
Handbook of Financial Econometrics and Statistics

Abstract

The literature has so far focused on the risk-return trade-off in equity markets and ignored alternative risky assets. This paper examines the presence and significance of an intertemporal relation between expected return and risk in the foreign exchange market. The paper provides new evidence on the intertemporal capital asset pricing model by using high-frequency intraday data on currency and by presenting significant time variation in the risk aversion parameter. Five-minute returns on the spot exchange rates of the US dollar vis-à-vis six major currencies (the euro, Japanese yen, British pound sterling, Swiss franc, Australian dollar, and Canadian dollar) are used to test the existence and significance of a daily risk-return trade-off in the FX market based on the GARCH, realized, and range volatility estimators. The results indicate a positive but statistically weak relation between risk and return on currency.

Our empirical analysis relies on the maximum likelihood estimation of the GARCH-in-mean models as described in Appendix 1. We also use the seemingly unrelated (SUR) regressions and panel data estimation to investigate the significance of a time-series relation between expected return and risk on currency as described in Appendix 2.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 849.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See French et al. (1987), Campbell (1987), Nelson (1991), Campbell and Hentschel (1992), Chan et al. (1992), Glosten et al. (1993), Scruggs (1998), Harvey (2001), Goyal and Santa-Clara (2003), Brandt and Kang (2004), Ghysels et al. (2005), Bali and Peng (2006), Christoffersen and Diebold (2006), Guo and Whitelaw (2006), Lundblad (2007), and Bali (2008).

  2. 2.

    A few exceptions are Chou et al. (1992), Harvey (2001), and Lettau and Ludvigson (2010).

  3. 3.

    As FX trading has evolved, several locations have emerged as market leaders. Currently, London contributes the greatest share of transactions with over 32 % of the total trades. Other trading centers – listed in order of volume – are New York, Tokyo, Zurich, Frankfurt, Hong Kong, Paris, and Sydney. Because these trading centers cover most of the major time zones, FX trading is a true 24-h market that operates 5 days a week.

  4. 4.

    In addition to “traditional” turnover of US $3.1 trillion in global foreign exchange market, US $2.1 trillion was traded in currency derivatives.

  5. 5.

    Note that volume percentages should add up to 200 %; 100 % for all the sellers and 100 % for all the buyers. As shown in Table 40.2, the market shares of seven major currencies add up to 180 %. The remaining 20 % of the total (200 %) market turnover has been accounted by other currencies from Europe and from other parts of the world.

  6. 6.

    See Keim and Stambaugh (1986), Chen et al. (1986), Campbell and Shiller (1988), Fama and French (1988, 1989), Campbell (1987, 1991), Ghysels et al (2005), and Guo and Whitelaw (2006).

  7. 7.

    We could not include the aggregate dividend yield (or the dividend-price ratio) because the data on dividends are available only at the monthly frequency while our empirical analyses are based on the daily data.

  8. 8.

    Assuming that the interest rate is 5 % per annum in the US and 2 % per annum in Japan, the uncovered interest rate parity predicts that the US dollar would depreciate against the Japanese yen by 3 %.

  9. 9.

    Jegadeesh (1990), Lehmann (1990), and Lo and MacKinlay (1990) provide evidence for the significance of short-term reversal (or negative autocorrelation) in short-term stock returns.

  10. 10.

    When testing monthly risk-return trade-off, French et al. (1987) use the monthly realized variance obtained from the sum of squared daily returns within a month.

  11. 11.

    Since the time-varying risk aversion coefficients from estimating Eqs. 40.12 and 40.13 with and without control variables turn out to be very similar, we only report results from the full specification of Eq. 40.13. Time-varying risk aversion estimates obtained from the parsimonious specification of Eq. 40.12 are available from the authors upon request.

  12. 12.

    Daily realized covariances between the exchange rates and the currency market and daily realized variance of the currency market are computed using 5-min returns in a day.

References

  • Abel, A. B. (1988). Stock prices under time-varying dividend risk: An exact solution in an infinite-horizon general equilibrium model. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 375–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alizadeh, S., Brandt, M. W., & Diebold, F. X. (2002). Range-based estimation of stochastic volatility models. Journal of Finance, 57, 1047–1092.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, T. G., Bollerslev, T., & Diebold, F. X. (2004). Parametric and nonparametric volatility measurement. In Y. Aït-Sahalia & L. P. Hansen (Eds.), Handbook of financial econometrics. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, T. G., Bollerslev, T., Diebold, F. X., & Ebens, H. (2001a). The distribution of realized stock return volatility. Journal of Financial Economics, 61, 43–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, T. G., Bollerslev, T., Diebold, F. X., & Labys, P. (2001b). The distribution of realized exchange rate volatility. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 96, 42–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, T. G., Bollerslev, T., Diebold, F. X., & Labys, P. (2003). Modeling and forecasting realized volatility. Econometrica, 71, 579–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backus, D. K., & Gregory, A. W. (1993). Theoretical relations between risk premiums and conditional variance. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 11, 177–185.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bali, T. G. (2008). The intertemporal relation between expected returns and risk. Journal of Financial Economics, 87, 101–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bali, T. G., & Engle, R. F. (2010). The intertemporal capital asset pricing model with dynamic conditional correlations. Journal of Monetary Economics, 57, 377–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bali, T. G., & Peng, L. (2006). Is there a risk-return tradeoff? Evidence from high frequency data. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 21, 1169–1198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollerslev, T. (1986). Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity. Journal of Econometrics, 31, 307–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollerslev, T., & Domowitz, I. (1993). Trading patterns and prices in the interbank foreign exchange market. Journal of Finance, 48, 1421–1443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollerslev, T., Engle, R. F., & Wooldridge, J. M. (1988). A capital asset pricing model with time-varying covariances. Journal of Political Economy, 96, 116–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollerslev, T., & Wooldridge, J. M. (1992). Quasi-maximum likelihood estimation and inference in dynamic models with time varying covariances. Econometric Reviews, 11, 143–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bollerslev, T., & Zhou, H. (2006). Volatility puzzles: A simple framework for gauging return-volatility regressions. Journal of Econometrics, 131, 123–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt, M. W., & Diebold, F. X. (2006). A no-arbitrage approach to range-based estimation of return covariances and correlations. Journal of Business, 79, 61–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt, M. W., & Kang, Q. (2004). On the relationship between the conditional mean and volatility of stock returns: A latent VAR approach. Journal of Financial Economics, 72, 217–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breen, W., Glosten, L. R., & Jagannathan, R. (1989). Economic significance of predictable variations in stock index returns. Journal of Finance, 44, 1177–1189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. Y. (1987). Stock returns and the term structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 18, 373–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. Y. (1991). A variance decomposition for stock returns. Economic Journal, 101, 157–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. Y., & Hentchel, L. (1992). No news is good news: An asymmetric model of changing volatility in stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 31, 281–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. Y., & Shiller, R. (1988). The dividend-price ratio and expectations of future dividends and discount factors. Review of Financial Studies, 1, 195–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, K. C., Karolyi, G. A., & Stulz, R. M. (1992). Global financial markets and the risk premium on U.S. equity. Journal of Financial Economics, 32, 137–167.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, N.-F., Roll, R., & Ross, S. A. (1986). Economic forces and the stock market. Journal of Business, 59, 383–403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chou, R., Engle, R. F., & Kane, A. (1992). Measuring risk aversion from excess returns on a stock index. Journal of Econometrics, 52, 201–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christoffersen, P. F., & Diebold, F. X. (2006). Financial asset returns, direction-of-change, forecasting, and volatility dynamics. Management Science, 52, 1273–1287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enders, W. (2009). Applied econometric time series (3rd ed.). New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Engle, R. F. (1982). Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity with estimates of the variance of United Kingdom inflation. Econometrica, 50, 987–1007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engle, R. F., Lilien, D. M., & Robins, R. P. (1987). Estimating time varying risk premia in the term structure: The ARCH M model. Econometrica, 55, 391–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1988). Dividend yields and expected stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 22, 3–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1989). Business conditions and expected returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics, 25, 23–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • French, K. R., Schwert, G. W., & Stambaugh, R. F. (1987). Expected stock returns and volatility. Journal of Financial Economics, 19, 3–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gennotte, G., & Marsh, T. A. (1993). Variations in economic uncertainty and risk premiums on capital assets. European Economic Review, 37, 1021–1041.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghysels, E., Santa-Clara, P., & Valkanov, R. (2005). There is a risk-return tradeoff after all. Journal of Financial Economics, 76, 509–548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glosten, L. R., Jagannathan, R., & Runkle, D. E. (1993). On the relation between the expected value and the volatility of the nominal excess returns on stocks. Journal of Finance, 48, 1779–1801.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goyal, A., & Santa-Clara, P. (2003). Idiosyncratic risk matters! Journal of Finance, 58, 975–1008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo, H., & Whitelaw, R. F. (2006). Uncovering the risk-return relation in the stock market. Journal of Finance, 61, 1433–1463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, P., & Zhang, H. (1999). An investigation of the risk and return relation at long horizons. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81, 399–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harvey, C. R. (2001). The specification of conditional expectations. Journal of Empirical Finance, 8, 573–638.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jegadeesh, N. (1990). Evidence of predictable behavior of security returns. Journal of Finance, 45, 881–898.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keim, D. B., & Stambaugh, R. F. (1986). Predicting returns in the stock and bond markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 17, 357–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lehmann, B. (1990). Fads, martingales, and market efficiency. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105, 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lettau, M., & Ludvigson, S. C. (2010). Measuring and modeling variation in the risk-return tradeoff. In Handbook of Financial Econometrics by Y. Ait-Sahalia & L. P. Hansen (Eds.), Vol 1, pp. 617–690. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lo, A. W., & MacKinlay, A. C. (1990). When are contrarian profits due to stock market overreaction? Review of Financial Studies, 3, 175–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundblad, C. (2007). The risk return tradeoff in the long run: 1836–2003. Journal of Financial Economics, 85, 123–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. C. (1973). An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica, 41, 867–887.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R. C. (1980). On estimating the expected return on the market: An exploratory investigation. Journal of Financial Economics, 8, 323–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, D. B. (1991). Conditional heteroskedasticity in asset returns: A new approach. Econometrica, 59, 347–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newey, W. K., & West, K. D. (1987). A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica, 55, 703–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parkinson, M. (1980). The extreme value method for estimating the variance of the rate of return. Journal of Business, 53, 61–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parks, R. W. (1967). Efficient estimation of a system of regression equations when disturbances are both serially and contemporaneously correlated. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 62, 500–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scruggs, J. T. (1998). Resolving the puzzling intertemporal relation between the market risk premium and conditional market variance: A two-factor approach. Journal of Finance, 53, 575–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sentana, E. (1995). Quadratic ARCH models. Review of Economic Studies, 62, 639–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsay, R. S. (2010). Analysis of financial time series. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner, C. M., Startz, R., & Nelson, C. R. (1989). A markov model of heteroskedasticity, risk, and learning in the stock market. Journal of Financial Economics, 25, 3–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2010). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data (2nd ed.). Boston: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Turan G. Bali .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1: Maximum Likelihood Estimation of GARCH-in-Mean Models

Modeling and estimating the volatility of financial time series has been high on the agenda of financial economists since the early 1980s. Engle (1982) put forward the Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedastic (ARCH) class of models for conditional variances which proved to be extremely useful for analyzing financial return series. Since then an extensive literature has been developed for modeling the conditional distribution of stock prices, interest rates, exchange rates, and futures prices. Following the introduction of ARCH models by Engle (1982) and their generalization by Bollerslev (1986), there have been numerous refinements of this approach to estimating conditional volatility. Most of the refinements have been driven by empirical regularities in financial data.

Engle (1982) introduces ARCH(p) model:

$$ {R}_{t+1}\equiv \alpha +{\varepsilon}_{t+1} $$
(40.22)
$$ \begin{array}{l}\ {\varepsilon}_{t+1}={z}_{t+1}\cdot {\sigma}_{t+1\left|t\right.},{z}_{t+1}\sim N\left(0,1\right),\\ {}E\left({\varepsilon}_{t+1}\right)=0\end{array} $$
(40.23)
$$ E\left({\varepsilon}_{t+1}^2\left|{\Omega}_t\right.\right)={\sigma}_{t+1\left|t\right.}^2={\gamma}_0+{\gamma}_1{\varepsilon}_t^2+{\gamma}_2{\varepsilon}_{t-1}^2+\dots +{\gamma}_p{\varepsilon}_{t-p}^2 $$
(40.24)
$$ f\left({R}_{t+1};\mu, {\sigma}_{t+1\left|t\right.}\right)=\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi {\sigma}_{t+1\left|t\right.}^2}} \exp \left[-\frac{1}{2}{\left(\frac{R_{t+1}-\mu }{\sigma_{t+1|t}}\right)}^2\right] $$
(40.25)

where R t+1 is the daily return for period t+1, μ = α is the constant conditional mean, ε t+1 = z t+1σ t+1|t is the error term with E(ε t +1) = 0, σ t+1|t is the conditional standard deviation of daily returns, and z t+1N(0,1) is a random variable drawn from the standard normal density and can be viewed as information shocks or unexpected news in the market. σ t+1|t 2 is the conditional variance of daily returns based on the information set up to time t denoted by Ω t . The conditional variance, σ t+1|t 2, follows an ARCH(p) process which is a function of the last period’s unexpected news (or information shocks). f(R t+1;μ,σ t+1|t ) is the conditional normal density function of R t+1 with the conditional mean of μ and conditional variance of σ t+1|t 2.

Given the initial values of ε t and, the parameters in Eqs 40.22 and 40.24 can be estimated by maximizing the log-likelihood function over the sample period. The conditional normal density in Eq. 40.25 yields the following log-likelihood function:

$$ \mathrm{Log}{L}_{ARCH}=-\frac{n}{2} \ln \left(2\pi \right)-\frac{n}{2} \ln {\sigma}_{t+1|t}-\frac{1}{2}{\displaystyle \sum_{t=1}^n{\left(\frac{R_{t+1}-\mu }{\sigma_{t+1|t}}\right)}^2} $$
(40.26)

Bollerslev (1986) extends the original work of Engle (1982) and defines the current conditional variance as a function of the last period’s unexpected news as well as the last period’s conditional volatility:

$$ {R}_{t+1}\equiv \alpha +{\varepsilon}_{t+1} $$
(40.27)
$$ {\varepsilon}_{t+1}={z}_{t+1}\cdot {\sigma}_{t+1|t},{z}_{t+1}\sim N\left(0,1\right)E\left({\varepsilon}_{t+1}\right)=0 $$
(40.28)
$$ E\left({\varepsilon}_{t+1}^2\left|{\Omega}_t\right.\right)={\sigma}_{t+1|t}^2={\gamma}_0+{\gamma}_1{\varepsilon}_t^2+{\gamma}_2{\sigma}_t^2 $$
(40.29)

where the conditional variance, σ t+1|t 2, in Eq. 40.29 follows a GARCH(1,1) process as defined by Bollerslev (1986) to be a function of the last period’s unexpected news (or information shocks), z t , and the last period’s variance, σ 2 t . The parameters in Eqs. 40.27, 40.28, and 40.29 are estimated by maximizing the conditional log-likelihood function in Eq. 40.26.

Engle et al. (1987) introduce the ARCH-in-mean model in which the conditional mean of financial time series is defined as a function of the conditional variance. In our empirical investigation of the ICAPM for exchange rates, we use the following GARCH-in-mean process to model the intertemporal relation between expected return and risk on currency

$$ {R}_{t+1}\equiv \alpha +\beta \cdot {\sigma}_{t+1|t}^2+{\varepsilon}_{t+1} $$
(40.30)
$$ \begin{array}{l}\ {\varepsilon}_{t+1}={z}_{t+1}\cdot {\sigma}_{t+1|t};{z}_{t+1}\sim N\left(0,1\right);\\ {}E\left({\varepsilon}_{t+1}\right)=0\end{array} $$
(40.31)
$$ E\left({\varepsilon}_{t+1}^2\left|{\Omega}_t\right.\right)={\sigma}_{t+1|t}^2={\gamma}_0+{\gamma}_1{\varepsilon}_t^2+{\gamma}_2{\sigma}_t^2 $$
(40.32)
$$ f\left({R}_{t+1};{\mu}_{t+1|t},{\sigma}_{t+1|t}\right)=\frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi {\sigma}_{t+1|t}^2}} \exp \left[-\frac{1}{2}{\left(\frac{R_{t+1}-{\mu}_{t+1|t}}{\sigma_{t+1|t}}\right)}^2\right] $$
(40.33)

where R t+1 is the daily return on exchange rates for period t+1, μ t+1|t α + βσ 2 t+1|t is the conditional mean for period t+1 based on the information set up to time t, ε t+1 = z t+1σ t+1|t is the error term with E t+1) = 0, σ t+1|t is the conditional standard deviation of daily returns on currency, and z t+1N(0,1) is a random variable drawn from the standard normal density and can be viewed as information shocks in the FX market. σ 2 t+1|t is the conditional variance of daily returns based on the information set up to time t denoted by Ω t . The conditional variance, σ 2 t+1|t , follows a GARCH(1,1) process as defined by Bollerslev (1986) to be a function of the last period’s unexpected news (or information shocks), z t , and the last period’s variance, σ t 2. f(R t+1;μ t+1|t ,σ t+1|t ) is the conditional normal density function of R t+1 with the conditional mean of μ t+1|t and conditional variance of σ 2 t+1|t .

Given the initial values of ε t and, the parameters in Eqs. 40.30 and 40.32 can be estimated by maximizing the log-likelihood function over the sample period. The conditional normal density in Eq. 40.33 yields the following log-likelihood function

$$ \begin{array}{c}\mathrm{Log}{L}_{ARCH}=-\frac{n}{2} \ln \left(2\pi \right)-\frac{n}{2} \ln {\sigma}_{t+1|t}\\ {}-\frac{1}{2}{\displaystyle \sum_{t=1}^n{\left(\frac{R_{t+1}-{\mu}_{t+1|t}}{\sigma_{t+1|t}}\right)}^2}\end{array} $$
(40.34)

where the conditional mean μ t+1|t α + βσ 2 t+1|t has two parameters and the conditional variance σ t+1|t 2 = γ 0 + γ 1ε t 2 + γ 2 σ 2 t has three parameters. Maximizing the log-likelihood in Eq. 40.34 yields the parameter estimates (α, β, γ 0, γ 1, γ 2).

The interested reader may wish to consult Enders (2009), Chap. 3, and Tsay (2010), Chap. 3, for comprehensive analysis of ARCH/GARCH models and their maximum likelihood estimation. Chapter 3 in Enders (2009) provides a detailed coverage of the basic ARCH and GARCH models, as well as the GARCH-in-mean processes and multivariate GARCH in some detail. Chapter 3 in Tsay (2010) provides a detailed coverage of the ARCH, GARCH, GARCH-M, the exponential GARCH, and Threshold GARCH models.

Appendix 2: Estimation of a System of Regression Equations

Consider a system of n equations, of which the typical ith equation is

$$ {y}_i={X}_i{\beta}_i+{u}_i $$
(40.35)

where y i is a N × 1 vector of time-series observations on the i th dependent variable, X i is a N × k i matrix of observations of k i independent variables, β i is a k i × 1 vector of unknown coefficients to be estimated, and u i is a N × 1 vector of random disturbance terms with mean zero. Parks (1967) proposes an estimation procedure that allows the error term to be both serially and cross-sectionally correlated. In particular, he assumes that the elements of the disturbance vector u follow an AR(1) process

$$ {u}_{it}={\rho}_i{u}_{it-1}+{\varepsilon}_{it};{\rho}_i<1 $$
(40.36)

where ɛ it is serially independently but contemporaneously correlated:

$$ \mathrm{Cov}\left({\varepsilon}_{it}{\varepsilon}_{jt}\right)={\sigma}_{ij},\forall i,j,\mathrm{and}\ \mathrm{Cov}\left({\varepsilon}_{it}{\varepsilon}_{js}\right)=0,\mathrm{for}\ s\ne t $$
(40.37)

Equation 40.35 can then be written as

$$ {y}_i={X}_i{\beta}_i+{P}_i{\varepsilon}_i, $$
(40.38)

with

$$ {P}_i=\left[\begin{array}{ccccc}\hfill {\left(1-{\rho}_i^2\right)}^{-1/2}\hfill & \hfill 0\hfill & \hfill 0\hfill & \hfill \dots \hfill & \hfill 0\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\rho}_i{\left(1-{\rho}_i^2\right)}^{-1/2}\hfill & \hfill 1\hfill & \hfill 0\hfill & \hfill \dots \hfill & \hfill 0\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\rho}_i^2{\left(1-{\rho}_i^2\right)}^{-1/2}\hfill & \hfill {\rho}_i\hfill & \hfill 0\hfill & \hfill \dots \hfill & \hfill 0\hfill \\ {}\hfill .\hfill & \hfill \hfill & \hfill \hfill & \hfill \hfill & \hfill \hfill \\ {}\hfill .\hfill & \hfill \hfill & \hfill \hfill & \hfill \hfill & \hfill \hfill \\ {}\hfill .\hfill & \hfill \hfill & \hfill \hfill & \hfill \hfill & \hfill \hfill \\ {}\hfill {\rho}_i^{N-1}{\left(1-{\rho}_i^2\right)}^{-1/2}\hfill & \hfill {\rho}_i^{N-2}\hfill & \hfill {\rho}_i^{N-3}\hfill & \hfill \dots \hfill & \hfill 1\hfill \end{array}\right] $$
(40.39)

Under this setup, Parks presents a consistent and asymptotically efficient three-step estimation technique for the regression coefficients. The first step uses single equation regressions to estimate the parameters of autoregressive model. The second step uses single equation regressions on transformed equations to estimate the contemporaneous covariances. Finally, the Aitken estimator is formed using the estimated covariance,

$$ \widehat{\beta}={\left({X}^T{\Omega}^{-1}X\right)}^{-1}{X}^T{\Omega}^{-1}y $$
(40.40)

Where Ω ≡ E[uu T] denotes the general covariance matrix of the innovation. In my application, I use the aforementioned methodology with the slope coefficients restricted to be the same for all portfolios. In particular, we use the same three-step procedure and the same covariance assumptions as in Eqs. 40.36, 40.37, 40.38, 40.39, and 40.40 to estimate the covariances and to generate the t-statistics for the parameter estimates.

The interested reader may wish to consult Wooldridge (2010), Chaps. 10.4, 10.5, and 10.6 for recent developments on panel data estimation. Chapter 10 in Wooldridge (2010) presents Basic Linear Unobserved Effects Panel Data Models, Chap. 10.4 provides Random Effects Methods, Chap. 10.5 contains Fixed Effects Methods, and Chap. 10.6 First Differencing Methods. Bali (2008) and Bali and Engle (2010) follow SUR estimation to investigate the empirical validity of the conditional intertemporal capital asset pricing models (ICAPM).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this entry

Cite this entry

Bali, T.G., Yilmaz, K. (2015). The Intertemporal Relation Between Expected Return and Risk on Currency. In: Lee, CF., Lee, J. (eds) Handbook of Financial Econometrics and Statistics. Springer, New York, NY. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-7750-1_40

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-7750-1_40

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, New York, NY

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-4614-7749-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4614-7750-1

  • eBook Packages: Business and Economics

Publish with us

Policies and ethics