Skip to main content

International Parity Conditions and Market Risk

  • Reference work entry
  • First Online:
Book cover Encyclopedia of Finance
  • 3722 Accesses

Abstract

This article presents a set of international parity conditions based on consistent and efficient market behavior. We hypothesize that deviations from parity conditions in international bond, stock, and commodity markets are attributable mainly to relative equity premiums and real interest rate differentials. Testing this hypothesis against four European markets for the recent floating currency period, we gain supportive evidence. Moreover, the deviations of uncovered interest parity, international stock return parity, and purchasing power parity are not independent; the evidence suggests that deviations from the three parities are driven by two common factors: equity premium differential and real interest rate differential.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 679.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 849.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Albuquerque, R., Bauer, G., and Schneider, M. (2004). “International equity flows and returns: A quantitative equilibrium approach.” Working Paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Abuaf, N. and Jorion, P. (1990). “Purchasing power parity in the long run.” Journal of Finance, 45: 157–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baillie, R.T. and Bollerslev, T. (1990). “A multivariate generalized ARCH approach to modeling risk premia in forward foreign exchange rate markets.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 9: 309–324.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baum, C.F., Barkoulas, J.T. and Caglayan, M. (2001). “Nonlinear adjustment to purchasing power parity in the post-Bretton Woods era.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 20: 379–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekaert, G. and Hodrick, R.J. (1993). “On biases in the measurement of foreign exchange risk premiums.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 12: 115–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Branson, W.H. (1988). “Comments on political vs. currency premia in international real interest differentials: a study of forward rates for 24 countries.” by J.A. Frankel and A.T. MacArthur. European Economic Review, 32: 1083–1114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J.Y. (1987). “Stock returns and the term structure.” Journal of Financial Economics, 18: 373–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, Y.W. and Lai, K.S. (1993). “Long-run purchasing power parity during the recent float.” Journal of International Economics, 34: 181–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, Y.W. and Lai, K.S. (1998). “Parity reversion in real exchange rates during the post-Bretton Woods period.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 17: 597–614.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiang, T.C. (1988). “The forward rate as a predictor of the future spot rate – a stochastic coefficient approach.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 20: 210–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiang, T.C. (1991). “International asset pricing and equity market risk.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 10: 349–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiang, T.C. and Trinidad, J. (1997). “Risk and international parity conditions: a synthesis from consumption-based models.” International Economic Journal, 11: 73–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, J.H. (2001). Asset Pricing. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornell, B. (1989). “The impact of data errors on measurement of the foreign exchange risk premium.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 8: 147–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cumby, R. (1990). “Consumption risk and international equity returns: some empirical evidence.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 9: 182–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Santis, G. and Gerard, B. (1998). “How big is the premium for currency risk?” Journal of Financial Economics, 49: 375–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Domowitz, I. and Hakkio, C.S. (1985). “Conditional variance and the risk premium in the foreign exchange market.” Journal of International Economics, 19: 47–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel, C. (1996). “The forward discount anomaly and the risk premium: a survey of recent evidence.” Journal of Empirical Finance, 3: 123–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F. (1975). “Short-term interest rates as predictors of inflation.” American Economic Review, 65: 269–282.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F. (1984). “Forward and spot exchange rates.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 14: 319–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, E. and Park, J. (1991). “Testing purchasing power parity under the null hypothesis of cointegration.” Economic Journal, 101: 1476–1484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleissig, A.R. and Strauss, J. (2000). “Panel unit root tests of purchasing power parity for price indices.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 19: 489–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J.A. (1979). “On the mark: a theory of floating exchange rates based on real interest differential.” American Economic Review, 69: 610–622.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J.A. and Froot, K.A. (1987). “Using survey data to test standard propositions regarding exchange rate expectations.” American Economic Review, 77: 133–153.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J.A. and MacArthur, A.T. (1988). “Political vs. currency premia in international real interest differentials: a study of forward rates for 24 countries.” European Economic Review, 32: 1083–1114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J.A. and Schmukler, A.L. (2000). “Country funds and asymmetric information.” International Journal of Finance and economics, 5: 177–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fratianni, M. and Wakeman, L.M. (1982). “The law of one price in the Eurocurrency market.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 3: 307–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel, J.A. (1981). “The collapse of purchasing power parities during the 1970s.” European Economic Review, 16: 145–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Froot, K.A. and Thaler, R.H. (1990). “Anomalies: foreign exchange.” Journal of Economic Perspective, 4: 179–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giovannini, A. and Jorion P. (1987). “Interest rates and risk premia in the stock market and in the foreign exchange market.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 6: 107–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gokey, T.C. (1994). “What explains the risk premium in foreign exchange returns.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 13: 729–738.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, L.P. and Hodrick, R.J. (1980). “Forward exchange rates as optimal predictors of future spot rates: an econometric analysis.” Journal of Political Economy, 88: 829–853.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodrick, R.J. (1987). The Empirical Evidence on the Efficiency of Forward and Futures Foreign Exchange Markets. New York: Harwood Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hu, X. (1997). “Macroeconomic uncertainty and the risk premium in the foreign exchange market.” International Journal of Finance and Finance, 16: 699–718.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, R.D. (1990). “Risk and parity in purchasing power.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 22: 338–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jiang, C. and Chiang, T.C. (2000). “Do foreign exchange risk premiums relate to the volatility in the foreign exchange and equity markets?” Applied Financial Economics, 10: 95–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jorian, P. and Sweeney, R.J. (1996). “Mean reversion in real exchange rates.” International Journal of Finance and Economics, 15: 535–550.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korajczyk, R.A. (1985). “The pricing of forward contracts for foreign exchange.” Journal of Political Economy, 93: 346–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korajczyk, R.A. and Viallet, C.J. (1992). “Equity risk premia and the pricing of foreign exchange risk.” Journal of International Economics, 33: 199–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (1978). “Purchasing power parity and exchange rate, another look at the evidence.” Journal of International Economics, 8: 397–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, R. (1989). “The pricing of forward exchange rates.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 8: 163–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lothian, J.R. and Taylor, M.P. (1997a). “The recent float from the perspective of the past two centuries.” Journal of Political Economy, 104: 488–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lothian, J.R. and Taylor, M.P. (1997b). “Real exchange rate behavior.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 16: 945–954.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E., Jr. (1982). “Interest rates and currency prices in a two-country world.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 10: 335–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mark, N.C. (1988). “Time-varying betas and risk premia in the pricing of forward foreign exchange contracts.” Journal of Financial Economics, 22: 335–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marston, R.C. (1997). “Tests of three parity conditions: distinguishing risk premia and systematic forecast errors.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 16: 285–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin, F.S. (1984). “Are real interest rates equal across countries: an empirical investigation of international parity conditions.” Journal of Finance, 39: 1345–1357.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newey, W.K. and West, K.D. (1987). “A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix.” Econometrica, 55: 703–708.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patel, J. (1990). “Purchasing power parity as a long run relation.” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 5: 367–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff, K. (1996). “The purchasing power parity puzzle.” Journal of Economic Literature, 34: 647–668.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roll, R. (1979). “Violations of purchasing power parity and their implications for efficient international commodity markets,” in M. Sarnat and G.P. Szego (eds.) International Finance and Trade. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roll, R. and Solnik, B. (1979). “On some parity conditions encountered frequently in international economics.” Journal of Macroeconomics, 1: 267–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roll, R. (1992). “Industrial structure and the comparative behavior of international stock market indexes.” Journal of Finance, 47: 3–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solnik, B. (1978). “International parity conditions and exchange risk.” Journal of Banking and Finance, 2: 281–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solnik, B. (1982). “An empirical investigation of the determinants of national interest rate differences.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 3: 333–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stulz, R.M. (1981). “A model of international asset pricing.” Journal of Financial Economics, 9: 383–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stulz, R.M. (1986). “Asset pricing and expected inflation.” Journal of Finance, 41: 209–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, M. (1988). “An empirical examination of long run purchasing power parity using cointegration techniques.” Applied Economics, 20: 1369–1381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagster, J.D. (1996). “Impact of the 1988 Basle Accord on international banks.” Journal of Finance, 51: 1321–1346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White, H. (1980). “A heteroscedasticity–consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroscedasticity.” Econometrica, 48: 55–68.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas C. Chiang .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

This Appendix provides additional empirical evidence on the popular parity conditions prevailing in international markets. The regression models are:

  1. A.

    Efficient Interest Rate Parity:

$$ {{s}_{{t + 1}}} - \left( {{{r}_t} - r_t^{*}} \right) = {{\beta }_0} + {{\beta }_1}{{s}_t} + {{\varepsilon }_{{t + 1}}} $$
  1. B.

    Efficient International Stock Parity:

$$ {{s}_{{t + 1}}} - \left( {{{R}_{{m,t + 1}}} - R_{{m,t + 1}}^{*}} \right) = {{\beta }_0} + {{\beta }_1}{{s}_t} + {{\varepsilon }_{{t + 1}}} $$
  1. C.

    Efficient Purchasing Power Parity:

$$ {{s}_{{t + 1}}} - \left( {\Delta {{p}_{{t + 1}}} - \Delta p_{{t + 1}}^{*}} \right) = {{\beta }_0} + {{\beta }_1}{{s}_t} + {{\varepsilon }_{{t + 1}}} $$
  1. D.

    International Fama Parity:

$$ \left( {\Delta {{p}_{{t + 1}}} - \Delta p_{{t + 1}}^{*}} \right) = {{\beta }_0} + {{\beta }_1}\left( {{{r}_t} - r_t^{*}} \right) + {{\varepsilon }_{{t + 1}}} $$
  1. E.

    Real Interest Rate Parity:

$$ {{\bar{r}}_{{t + 1}}} = {{\beta }_0} + {{\beta }_1}\bar{r}_{{t + 1}}^{*} + {{\varepsilon }_{{t + 1}}} $$
  1. F.

    Equity Premium Parity:

$$ {{R}_{{m,t + 1}}} - {{r}_t} = {{\beta }_0} + {{\beta }_1}\left( {R_{{m,t + 1}}^{*} - r_t^{*}} \right) + {{\varepsilon }_{{t + 1}}} $$
  1. G.

    Covered Interest Rate Parity:

$$ {{r}_t} - r_t^{*} = {{\beta }_0} + {{\beta }_1}({{f}_t} - {{s}_t}) + {{\varepsilon }_t} $$
  1. H.

    Unbiased Forward-Rate Hypothesis I:

$$ {{f}_t} - {{s}_{{t + 1}}} = {{\beta }_0} + {{\beta }_1}\left( {{{f}_t} - {{s}_t}} \right) + {{\varepsilon }_{{t + 1}}} $$
  1. I.

    Unbiased Forward-Rate Hypothesis II:

$$ {{s}_{{t + 1}}} - {{s}_t} = {{\beta \prime}_0} + {{\beta \prime}_{1}}\left( {{{f}_{t}} - {{s}_l}} \right) + {{\varepsilon \prime}_{{t + 1}}} $$
Table A.1 Estimates of international parity conditions

Models A through C are efficient versions of the UIP, ISP, and PPP proposed by Roll (1979). An efficient market implies that β 0 = 0 and β 1 = 1. The evidence presented in Panels A, B, and C of Table A.1 is quite consistent with the efficient nature of the spot exchange rate, suggesting that all information concerning future exchange rate adjusted return differentials is incorporated into the current spot exchange rate. The supportive evidence holds true for all three parity conditions. However, it should be pointed out that specifying the model in this form tends to lead to not rejecting the efficient-market hypothesis. In particular, Roll’s specification is more or less to test spot exchange rate efficiency rather than to test parity conditions. If we check the estimated equations, the series of return differentials is stationary and its magnitude is rather small as compared with the level of exchange rates. As a result, the dominance of the lagged exchange rate variable in the test equation gives rise to a high R-square.

Next let us consider the efficient-market hypothesis for U.S. Treasury bills. Fama (1975) argues that the 1-month nominal interest rate can be viewed as a predictor of the inflation rate. Applying this notion in international markets implies that the nominal interest rate differential can be used to predict the inflation rate differential. The evidence in Panel D does provide some predictive evidence for the German and Swiss markets. However, the efficient-market hypothesis is rejected in the international context. This also casts doubt on the validity of real interest rate parity. The results from Panel E confirm this point; the correlations of real interest rates for three of the four markets are positive and statistically significant, but the parity condition still fails. The reasons advanced by Korajczyk (1985) are the existence of risk premiums and market imperfections.

In the text as well as in the finance literature, we are concerned with the relationship between stock equity premiums. The evidence derived from Panel F indicates that the correlation for each country is highly significant, although we are unable to find strong support for the parity condition. If we view the U.S. equity premium as a proxy for the world-portfolio premium, the slope coefficient for each estimated equation can be treated virtually as a beta coefficient in light of the CAPM framework.16

Panel G contains the results for testing covered interest rate parity. Since all the variables in this equation are directly observable and readily assessed by economic agents, the estimated equation is closest to the parity condition. It is generally recognized that arbitrage profit derived from this equation is very negligible, if there is any. Thus, any gap in this equation must reflect country risk (Frankel and MacArthur, 1988), transaction costs (Fratianni and Wakeman, 1982), or simply data errors.

The forward premium (or discount) has been commonly used to predict foreign-exchange risk premiums as well as currency depreciation as denoted by the equations in Panels H and I. The unbiasedness hypothesis in Panel H requires that β 0 = β 1 = 0; however, the unbiasedness hypothesis in Panel I implies that \( {{\beta \prime}_0} = 0 \) and \( {{\beta \prime}_1} = 1 \) (Hansen and Hodrick, 1980; Cornell, 1989; Bekaert and Hodrick, 1993). Fama (1984) notes the complementarity of the regressions in Panels H and I and suggests that \( {{\beta }_0} = - {{\beta \prime}_0} \), that \( {{\beta }_1} = 1 - {{\beta \prime}_1} \), and that \( {{\varepsilon }_{{t + 1}}} = - {{\varepsilon \prime}_{{t + 1}}} \). Consistent with the existing literature, the evidence presented in Panel H and Panel I apparently rejects the unbiasedness hypothesis.17 However, the complementary nature of the coefficients appears consistent with Fama’s argument. The puzzle entailed in this set of equations is that the estimated slope in the Panel I equation is typically negative. This interpretation has been attributable to risk premium (Fama, 1984; Giovannini and Jorion, 1987; Hodrick, 1987; Mark, 1988; and Jiang and Chiang, 2000), forecast errors (Froot and Thaler, 1990), and regime shifting (Chiang, 1988; Bekaert and Hodrick, 1993).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2013 Springer Science+Business Media New York

About this entry

Cite this entry

Chiang, T.C. (2013). International Parity Conditions and Market Risk. In: Lee, CF., Lee, A. (eds) Encyclopedia of Finance. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-5360-4_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-5360-4_7

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Boston, MA

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-4614-5359-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4614-5360-4

  • eBook Packages: Business and Economics

Publish with us

Policies and ethics