Encyclopedia of Creativity, Invention, Innovation and Entrepreneurship

2013 Edition
| Editors: Elias G. Carayannis

Patents and Entrepreneurship

  • Julien Pénin
Reference work entry
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-3858-8_416

Synonyms

 Innovation policy;  Intellectual property rights;  Markets for technology;  Open innovation;  R&D collaboration

A patent gives to its owner an exclusive right on a product or process which is new, inventive, and has an industrial application (in the USA, this third criterion is broader in the sense that the invention needs not to have an industrial application but must merely be useful). From a legal point of view, a patent is a negative right. It gives the right to exclude but not necessarily to use an invention, if this use leads to infringe a right held by someone else. The maximum duration of the patent protection is 20 years after the first application (but a majority of patents does not last this long). Also, in most countries, patent applicants must provide a description of their invention which, 18 months after the first application, is made public (made available to everybody). The description must be sufficiently clear and exhaustive in order to allow a person...

This is a preview of subscription content, log in to check access.

References

  1. Arora A, Fosfuri A, Gambardella A. Markets for technology: the economics of innovation and corporate strategy. Cambridge: MIT press; Mass 2001.Google Scholar
  2. Arora A, Merges R. Specialized supply firms, property rights and firm boundaries. Ind Corp Change. 2004;13:451–75.Google Scholar
  3. Arrow KJ. Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In: The rate and direction of inventive activity: economic and social factors. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1962. p. 609–25.Google Scholar
  4. Chesbrough H. Open innovation: the new imperative for creating and profiting from technology. Boston: Harvard Business School Press; 2003.Google Scholar
  5. Cohen WM, Nelson RR, Walsh J. Protecting their intellectual assets: appropriability conditions and why US manufacturing firms patent (or not). NBER working paper 7552, 2000.Google Scholar
  6. Grindley P, Teece D. Managing intellectual capital: licensing and cross-licensing in semi-conductors and electronics. Calif Manage Rev. 1997;39:8–41.Google Scholar
  7. Heller MA, Eisenberg RS. Can patents deter innovation? The anticommons in biomedical research. Science. 1998;280:698–701.Google Scholar
  8. Jaffe A. The US patent system in transition: policy innovation and the innovation process. Res Policy. 2000;29:531–57.Google Scholar
  9. Jaffe A, Lerner J. Innovation and its discontents: how our broken patent system is endangering innovation and progress, and what to do about it. Princeton: Princeton University Press; 2004.Google Scholar
  10. Kingston W. Innovation needs patent reform. Res Policy. 2001;30:403–23.Google Scholar
  11. Levin RC, Klevorick K, Nelson RR, Winter S. Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development. Brooking Pap Econ Activity. 1987;3:783–820.Google Scholar
  12. Mazzoleni R, Nelson RR. The benefits and costs of strong patent protection: a contribution to the current debate. Res Policy. 1998;27:273–84.Google Scholar
  13. Pénin J, Wack J-P. Research tool patents and free-libre biotechnology: a unified perspective. Res Policy. 2008;37(10):1909–21.Google Scholar
  14. Scotchmer S. Innovation and incentives. Cambridge: MIT Press; 2004.Google Scholar
  15. Shapiro C. Navigating the patent thicket: cross licenses, patent pools, and standard setting. Innov Policy Econ. 2000;1:119–50.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media LLC 2013

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.University of Strasbourg – BETA (UMR 7522 CNRS-UdS)Strasbourg CedexFrance