Skip to main content

Updating the Reference Level: Experimental Evidence

  • Conference paper
Experimental Business Research

Abstract

Empirical findings suggest that in decisions under uncertainty people evaluate outcomes relative to a reference level: they are risk seeking in the domain of losses and risk averse in the domain of gains. This finding is used in the finance literature to predict/explain the “disposition effect,” which is the tendency of investors to sell assets that have gained value (“winners”) too early and ride assets that have lost value (“losers”) too long. The current experiment was designed to overcome some of the difficulties involved in using real market data to test the disposition effect. One of the main goals was to find evidence on how prior gains and losses influence the risk behavior of people, by shifting the reference level. The results were consistent with the disposition effect hypothesis. Furthermore, it was found that the data are best described by assuming that participants use the historical peak of the process as a reference level.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Arrow, K. J. (1965). Aspects of the Theory of Risk-Bearing, Helsinki: Yrjo Hahnsson Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1971). Essays in the Theory of Risk-Bearing, Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binswanger, H. P. (1981). “Attitudes toward Risk: Theoretical Implications of an Experiment in Rural India.” Economic Journal, 91, 867–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brealey, R. A., and S. C. Myers (1988). Principles of Corporate Finance, New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Constantinides, G. M. (1983). “Capital market equilibrium with personal tax.” Econometrica, 51, 611–636.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Constantinides, G. M. (1984). “Optimal stock trading with personal taxes: Implications for prices and the abnormal January effect.” Journal of Financial Economics, 13, 65–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bondt, W. F. M., and R. H. Thaler (1994). “Financial decision making in markets and firms: A behavioral perspective.” NBER Working Paper 4777.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dufwenberg, M. & A. Muren (2002). “Discrimination by gender and social distance”, Working Paper 2002:2, Department of Economics, Stockholm University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, W. (1992). “Toward the demise of economic man and woman: Bottom lines from Santa Cruz.” in Utility theories: Measurements and applications. Ed Ward. Edwards. Kluwer Academic Publishers, 253–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. F. (1991). “Efficient capital markets: II.” Journal of Finance, 46,5, 1575–1617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferris, S. P., R. A. Haugen, and A. K. Makhija (1988). “Predicting contemporary volume with historic volume at differential price levels: Evidence supporting the disposition effect.” Journal of Finance, 43, 677–699.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C., and G. A. Kochenberger (1979). “Two-piece von Neumann-Morgenstern utility functions.” Decision Science, 10, 503–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gneezy, U. (1996). “Probability judgment in multi-stage problems: Experimental evidence of systematic biases.” Acta Psychologica, 93, 59–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, P. J. (1988). “Consequentialism and the independence axiom,” in Risk, Decision and Rationality. Ed. Bertrand Munier. Dordrecht, Holland: D. Reidel Publishing Co., 503–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heath, C, S. Huddart, and M. Lang (1999). “Psychological factors and stock option exercise.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114,2, 601–627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hershey, J. C., H. C. Kunreuther, and P. J. H. Schoemaker (1982). “Sources of bias in assessment procedures for utility functions.” Management Science, 28, 936–954.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., J. L. Knetsch, and R. H. Thaler (1991). “Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5, 193–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., and A. Tversky (1979). “Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk.” Econometrica, 47, 263–91.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Karni, E., and D. Schmeidler (1991). “Atemporal dynamic consistency and expected utility theory.” Journal of Economic Theory, 54, 401–408.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D. M. (1988). Notes on the Theory of Choice, Boulder, Co: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lakonishok, J., and S. Smidt (1986). “Capital gain taxation and volume of trading.” Journal of Finance, 41, 951–974.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Machina, M. J. (1989). “Dynamic consistency and non-expected utility model of choice under uncertainty.” Journal of Economic Literature, 1622–1668.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz, H. (1952). “The utility of wealth.” Journal of Political Economy, 60, 151–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Payne, J. W., D. J. Laughhunn, and R. Crum (1980). “Translation of gambles and aspiration level effects in risky choice behavior.” Management Science, 26, 1039–1060.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Odean, T. (1998). “Are investors reluctant to realize rgeir losses?” Journal of Finance, 53, 1775–1798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pratt, J. W. (1964). “Risk aversion in the small and in the large.” Econometrica, 32, 122–136.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport, A., R. Zwick, and S. G. Funk (1988). “Selection of portfolios with risky and riskless assets: Experimental tests of two expected utility models.” Journal of Economic Psychology, 9, 169–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport, A. (1984). “Effects of wealth on portfolios under various investment conditions.” Acta Psychologica, 55, 31–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. M. (1989). Introduction to Probability Models, London: Academic Press.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Savage, L. J. (1954). The Foundation of Statistics, New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selten, R. (1991). “Properties of a measure of predictive success.” Mathematical Social Science, 21, 153–167.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Selten, R., and S. Krischker (1983). “Comparison of two theories for characteristic function experiments,” in Aspiration Levels in Bargaining and Economic Decision Making. Ed. R. Tietz, Springer. Berlin and Heidelberg, 259–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shefrin, H. M., and M. Statman (1985). “The disposition to sell winners too early and ride losers too long.” Journal of Finance, 40, 777–790.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H., and E. J. Johnson (1990). “Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: The effects of prior outcomes on risky choice.” Management Science, 36, 643–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thatcher, A. R. (1957). “Studies in the history of probability and statistics VI. A note on the early solutions of the duration of the play.” Biometrika 44, 515–518.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman (1991). “Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference-dependent model.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 1039–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., and D. Kahneman (1992). “Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297–323.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Volij, O. (1994). “Dynamic consistency, consequentialism and reduction of compound lotteries.” Economics Letters, 46, 121–129.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M., and C. F. Camerer (1998). “The disposition effect in securities trading: An experimental analysis.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 33, 167–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2005 Springer

About this paper

Cite this paper

Gneezy, U. (2005). Updating the Reference Level: Experimental Evidence. In: Zwick, R., Rapoport, A. (eds) Experimental Business Research. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/0-387-24244-9_12

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics