Skip to main content

Mechanisms in a Digitalized World

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Social Design

Part of the book series: Studies in Economic Design ((DESI))

  • 527 Accesses

Abstract

Due to computing and communication facilities, formal procedures, often referred to as “algorithms,” are now extensively used in public, economic, and social areas. These procedures, currently at the forefront of criticisms, share some features with mechanisms as defined by economists, following Hurwicz. My aim is to investigate these relationships and to discuss some of the economic risks generated by the power of algorithms.

This is written for the volume “Social Design: Essays in Memory of Leonid Hurwicz” edited by Walter Trockel. I thank him for his encouragement. This work is partially based on a talk I gave in the stimulating workshop “Social Responsibility of Algorithms” organized by Alexis Tsoukias at Paris-Dauphine University, December 2017.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Naturally, the relationships do not apply to all algorithms, in particular to those computed in artificial intelligence.

  2. 2.

    Such argument has the same flavor as the one saying that contracts are typically incomplete.

  3. 3.

    This question is very much related to the previous one, as noted by Dwork et al. (2001).

  4. 4.

    As described in McMillan (1994), options were multiple, for example simultaneous versus sequential auctions, open versus sealed bids, or royalties versus reserve prices.

  5. 5.

    The APB procedure did not satisfy this property because it modified the deferred-acceptance algorithm so that universities’ choices depended on the students rankings. Though, students’ misreporting their preferences does not seem to have been a big issue.

  6. 6.

    Another example of reluctance to automatic systems is Centrelink put in place in Australia to recover social security overpayments. Though the system, dubbed “Robodebt” by users, had some flaws initially—people being unable to complain or reach the service—the main objection relied on the automatic nature of the procedure. Information can be found in https://www.humanservices.gov.au/organisations/about-us/publications-and-resources/government-response-community-affairs-references-committee-report.

  7. 7.

    Each student will first select a list of applications without order; each application in the list is sent to the corresponding university. Then there will be a succession of rejection or acceptance by universities and students (on their list). The number of applications in a list is a priori constrained to 10, but each application may regroup up to 20 slots.

  8. 8.

    An equilibrium as defined by Nash solves this feedback. Wilson (1967) provides a first analysis of the bidders’ strategies in an equilibrium context, further developed by Milgrom and Weber (1982).

  9. 9.

    This is not true for new algorithmic methods such as machine learning with evolving data, neuronal networks and all the techniques referred to as “artificial intelligence.”

  10. 10.

    More information can be found at http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-17-1784_en.htm.

  11. 11.

    Clive Humby, a data scientist, claimed in 2006 “Data is the new oil,” now a popular maxim.

  12. 12.

    https://www.eugdpr.org/.

  13. 13.

    Balinski and Demange (2018) study whether tax instruments are useful in reducing excessive level of data collection.

  14. 14.

    I am grateful to Carmine Ventre for calling my attention on this point. For more information, see e.g. the book edited by Easley et al. (2014), in particular Chapter 4 by Golub, Dupuis and Olsen and Chapter 10 by Linton, O’Hara and Zigrand.

References

  • Arrow, K. J. (1950). A difficulty in the concept of social welfare. Journal of Political Economy, 58(4), 328–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1951) . Social choice and individual values (Vol. 12). London: Yale University Press (3rd ed. 2012).

    Google Scholar 

  • Balinski, M.L., & Demange, G. (1989). An axiomatic approach to proportionality between matrices. Mathematics of Operations Research, 14(4), 700–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, F., & Demange, G. (2018). Taxation and privacy protection on Internet platforms. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 20(1), 52–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlson, M. A. (2007). A brief history of the 1987 stock market crash with a discussion of the federal reserve response. Downlable at https://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2007/.../200713pap.pdf

  • Chen, L., Mislove, A., & Wilson, C. (2016). An empirical analysis of algorithmic pricing on amazon marketplace. In Proceedings of the 25th International Conference on World Wide Web (pp. 1339–1349).

    Google Scholar 

  • Cramton P., Shoham Y., & Steinberg, R. (Eds.). (2006). Combinatorial auctions. Cambridge, London: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demange, G., & Gale, D. (1985). The strategy structure of two-sided matching markets. Econometrica, 53, 873–888.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubins, L. E., & Freedman, D. A. (1981). Machiavelli and the Gale-Shapley algorithm. The American Mathematical Monthly, 88(7), 485–494.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dwork, C., Kumar, R., Naor, M., & Sivakumar, D. (2001). Rank aggregation methods for the web. In Proceedings of the 10th International Conference on World Wide Web (pp. 613–622). New York: ACM.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easley, D., Prado, M. L. D., & O’Hara, M. (2014). High-frequency trading: New realities for traders, markets and regulators. London: Risk Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gale, D., & Shapley, L. S. (1962). College admissions and the stability of marriage. The American Mathematical Monthly, 69(1), 9–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldman, J., & Procaccia, A. D. (2015). Spliddit: Unleashing fair division algorithms. ACM SIGecom Exchanges, 13(2), 41–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hurwicz, L. (1960). Optimality and informational efficiency in resource allocation processes (pp. 27–46). Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hurwicz, L. (1973). The design of mechanisms for resource allocation. The American Economic Review, 63(2), 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hurwicz, L. (2008). But who will guard the guardians? The American Economic Review, 98(3), 577–585.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McMillan, J. (1994). Selling spectrum rights. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(3), 145–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. R., & Weber, R. J. (1982). A theory of auctions and competitive bidding. Econometrica, 50, 1089–1122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, R. S., & Shorter, G. (2016). High-frequency trading: Overview of recent developments. CRS Report, 44443.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (2009). Fundamental theory of institutions: a lecture in honor of Leo Hurwicz. Review of Economic Design, 13(1–2), 59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B., & Satterthwaite, M. A. (1983). Efficient mechanisms for bilateral trading. Journal of Economic Theory, 29(2), 265–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nisan, N., & Ronen, A. (2001). Algorithmic mechanism design. Games and Economic Behavior, 35(1–2), 166–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Page, L., Brin, S., Motwani, R., & Winograd, T. (1999). The PageRank citation ranking: Bringing order to the web. Venue: Stanford InfoLab.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E. (2008). Deferred acceptance algorithms: History, theory, practice, and open questions. International Journal of Game Theory, 36(3–4), 537–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E., Sönmez, T., & Ünver, M. U. (2004). Kidney exchange. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 457–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1964). A theory of oligopoly. Journal of Political Economy, 72(1), 44–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomson, W. (1990). The consistency principle. Game Theory and Applications, 187, 215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H. R. (2007). Position auctions. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 25(6), 1163–1178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vickrey, W. (1961). Counterspeculation, auctions, and competitive sealed tenders. The Journal of Finance, 16(1), 8–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, R. B. (1967). Competitive bidding with asymmetric information. Management Science, 13(11), 816–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young, H. P., (1987). On dividing an amount according to individual claims or liabilities. Mathematics of Operations Research, 12(3), 398–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gabrielle Demange .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Demange, G. (2019). Mechanisms in a Digitalized World. In: Trockel, W. (eds) Social Design. Studies in Economic Design. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-93809-7_19

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics