Skip to main content

The Bank of Amsterdam Through the Lens of Monetary Competition

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: Financial and Monetary Policy Studies ((FMPS,volume 39))

Abstract

We examine the experience of an innovative fiat money regime, introduced by the Bank of Amsterdam in the late seventeenth century and persisting until the downfall of the Dutch Republic in 1795. The pan-European competition among international monies occurred beyond the legal domain of any one political authority, or cluster of local authorities. Competition was not framed by legally derived spillovers, so bad money was shunned.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The 1930 Brecht/Weill opera takes place in a city where it is a crime to be caught without money.

  2. 2.

    In J.M. Barrie’s work, fairies exist only if enough people believe in them.

  3. 3.

    The rise of the Amsterdam bill market coincides with the general economic expansion of the Dutch Republic during the Golden Age, and it is difficult to sort out the marginal contribution provided by the Bank of Amsterdam. As has been emphasized by various authors (e.g., Spufford 2006), however, the strength of Amsterdam’s institutions allowed it to thrive as a financial center, even after economic growth had largely ceased.

  4. 4.

    The guilder was a ‘ghost money’ (Sargent and Velde 2002: 126), a coin that no longer circulated but continued to serve as a unit of account.

  5. 5.

    This was possible given contemporary technology for metal assay. Detection of silver fineness by touchstone was accurate to 3 % at best (Gandal and Sussman 1997: 444). Weight could be accurately assayed only with large amounts of coins.

  6. 6.

    The early ledgers of the Bank have unfortunately been lost, so we have no direct proof that such ‘giro’ payments immediately became the norm in Amsterdam. However contemporaneous ledgers from a similar exchange bank in Middelburg were examined by Van Dillen (1964a: 350) who found extensive use of giro settlement.

  7. 7.

    To give some perspective on these figures, consider that a contemporary daily wage for an unskilled laborer would have been approximately one guilder (de Vries and van de Woude 1997: Table 12.5). A typical bill of exchange would have been for one to two thousand guilders.

  8. 8.

    Calculated by the authors using the Van Cauwenberghe and Verachten (2012) data set.

  9. 9.

    Confusingly, the new dukaat became known as a rijksdaalder, the new rijder as a ducaton, and the old rijksdaalder as a bank rijksdaalder. See for example the Bank inventory of 1711 (AMA 5077/1355, folio 1–2).

  10. 10.

    By structuring the receipt as an option rather than evidence of a debt, the Bank was able to guarantee its priority as a creditor. This meant that the Bank could offer what were essentially collateralized loans on advantageous terms, i.e., at lower interest rates and lower collateral haircuts than could a private lender (Mees 1838).

  11. 11.

    Annual fee revenue calculated by subtracting interest revenue from total revenue for each year. All data from AMA 5077/1318–1322.

  12. 12.

    A noteworthy contrast is provided by the more direct approach of another contemporary municipal bank, the Bank of Hamburg. Beginning in 1770, the Hamburg institution explicitly defined its accounts as a claim on silver bullion rather than coin, and always stood ready to buy and sell bullion at posted prices (Sieveking 1934: 150).

  13. 13.

    These figures were collected by Simon Hart (AMA 883/405).

References

Archives

  • Amsterdam Municipal Archives (Stadsarchief Amsterdam): AMA.

    Google Scholar 

Literature

  • Boyer-Xambeu, M. T., Deleplace, G., & Gillard, L. (1994). Private money and public currencies. New York: M.E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlos, A., & Neal, L. (2011). Amsterdam and London as financial centers in the eighteenth century. Financial History Review, 18, 21–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dehing, P., & ‘t Hart, M. (1997). Linking the fortunes, currency and banking, 1550–1800. In M. ‘t Hart, J. Jonker, & J. L. van Zanden (Eds.), A Financial History of the Netherlands (pp. 37–63). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • De Jong-Keesing, E. E. (1939). De Economische Crisis van 1763 te Amsterdam. Amsterdam: N.V. Intern. Uitgevers en h. Mij.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Vries, J., & van der Woude, A. (1997). The first modern economy, success, failure and perseverance of the Dutch Economy, 1500–1815. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Flandreau, M., Galimard, C., Jobst, C., & Nogues-Marco, P. (2009). Monetary geography before the industrial revolution. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 2, 149–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gandal, N., & Sussman, N. (1997). Asymmetric information and commodity money: tickling the tolerance in medieval France. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 19, 440–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gillard, L. (2004). La banque d’Amsterdam et le florin européen au temps de la République neerlandaise, 1610–1820. Paris: L’École des hautes études en sciences sociales.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, C. M., & Roberds, W. (2009). ‘Why pay? An introduction to the economics of payments. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 18, 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCusker, J. J. (1978). Money and exchange in Europe and America, 1600–1775: A handbook. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mees, W. C. (1838). Proeve eener Geschiedenis van het Bankwezen in Nederland geduerende den Tijd der Republiek. Rotterdam: W. Messcuert.

    Google Scholar 

  • Munro, JH. (2012). The technology and economics of coinage debasement in medieval and early modern Europe: with special reference to the low countries and England. Working Paper 456. Toronto: University of Toronto, Department of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neal, L. (2000). How it all began: the monetary and financial architecture of Europe during the first global capital markets, 1648–1815. Financial History Review, 7, 117–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neal, L., & Quinn, S. (2001). Networks of information, markets, and institutions in the rise of London as a financial centre. Financial History Review, 8, 7–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polak, M. (1998a). Historiografie en Economie van de ‘Muntchaos’. Deel I, Amsterdam: NEHA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polak, M. (1998b). Historiografie en Economie van de ‘Muntchaos’. Deel II: Bijlagen, Amsterdam: NEHA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quinn, S., & Roberds, W. (2007). The Bank of Amsterdam and the leap to Central Bank money. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 97, 262–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quinn, S., & Roberds, W. (2009a). An economic explanation of the early Bank of Amsterdam, debasement, bills of exchange and the emergence of the first central bank. In J. Atack & L. Neal (Eds.), The evolution of financial institutions from the seventeenth to the twentieth-first century (pp. 32–70). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quinn, S., & Roberds, W. (2009b). Coinage, central bank money and the Bank of Amsterdam. In M. van Nieuwkerk (Ed.), The Bank of Amsterdam: On the origins of central banking (pp. 92–107). Amsterdam: Sonsbeek Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quinn, S., Roberds, W. (2010). How Amsterdam got fiat money. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper 2010–2017. Atlanta: Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quinn, S., Roberds, W. (2012). Responding to a shadow banking crisis: The lessons of 1763. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Working Paper 2012–2018. Atlanta: Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rolnick, A., Velde, F., & Weber, W. E. (1996). The debasement puzzle: An essay on medieval monetary history. Journal of Economic History, 56, 789–808.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sargent, T. J., & Velde, F. (2002). The big problem of small change. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schnabel, Isabel, & Shin, Hyun Song. (2004). Liquidity and contagion: The crisis of 1763. Journal of the European Economic Association, 2, 929–968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sieveking, H. (1934). Die Hamburger Bank. In J. G. van Dillen (Ed.), History of the Principal Public Banks (pp. 125–160). The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spufford, Peter. (2006). From Antwerp and Amsterdam to London: The decline of financial centres in Europe. De Economist, 154, 143–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1776/1937). The wealth of nations. New York: Modern Library.

    Google Scholar 

  • Uittenbogaard, R. (2009). Lending by the Bank of Amsterdam (1609–1802). In M. van Nieuwkerk (Ed.), The Bank of Amsterdam: On the origins of central banking (pp. 120–131). Amsterdam: Sonsbeek Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Cauwenberghe E., & Verachten, L. (2012). Dataset monetaire geschiedenis van de Zuidelijke Nederlanden, 1493–1789. Retrieved at geldmuseum.nl/museum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Dillen, J. G. (1921). Een boek van phoonsen over de Amsterdamsche Wisselbank. Economisch-historish jaarboek, 7, 1–146.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Dillen, J. G. (1934). The Bank of Amsterdam. In J. G. Van Dillen (Ed.), History of the principal public banks (pp. 79–124). The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Dillen, J. G. (1964a). Bloeitijd der Amsterdamse Wisselbank 1687–1781. In J. G. van Dillen (Ed.), Mensen en Achtergronden (Studies uitgegeven ter gelegenheid van de tachtigste jaardag van de schrijver) (pp. 385–415). J.B. Wolters: Groningen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Dillen, J. G. (1964b). Ondergang van de Amsterdamse Wisselbank, 1782–1820. In J. G. van Dillen (Ed.), Mensen en Achtergronden (Studies uitgegeven ter gelegenheid van de tachtigste jaardag van de schrijver) (pp. 416–447). J.B. Wolters: Groningen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Dillen, J. G. (1964c). Oprichting en Functie der Amsterdamse Wisselbank in de zeventiende Eeuw 1609–1686. In J. G. van Dillen (Ed.), Mensen en Achtergronden (Studies uitgegeven ter gelegenheid van de tachtigste jaardag van de schrijver) (pp. 337–384). J.B. Wolters: Groningen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Nieuwkerk, M. (Ed.). (2009). The Bank of Amsterdam: On the origins of central banking. Amsterdam: Sonsbeek Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stephen Quinn .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Quinn, S., Roberds, W. (2014). The Bank of Amsterdam Through the Lens of Monetary Competition. In: Bernholz, P., Vaubel, R. (eds) Explaining Monetary and Financial Innovation. Financial and Monetary Policy Studies, vol 39. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-06109-2_11

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics