Skip to main content

Statistics, Social Science, and Social Justice: The Zemstvo Statisticians of Pre-Revolutionary Russia

  • Chapter
Russia in the European Context, 1789–1914

Abstract

Ever since the eighteenth century, the ideals of the Enlightenment inspired educated people the world over to believe not only that human beings could by their own efforts discover the universal laws and scientific principles that govern human and nonhuman behavior, but to assume as well that the pursuit of scientific knowledge would serve the cause of justice. That Enlightenment universals and scientific knowledge could be deployed to support unjust causes, or to reinforce a variety of despotisms and oppressions was inconceivable to the philosophes, and a vexed question for later proponents of radical and revolutionary change. On the other hand, there have always been plenty of scholars and policy-makers for whom Enlightenment universals and scientific knowledge provided a welcome promise of stability, order, and incremental change within quite undemocratic and economically polarized societies. So, from the outset, the “social sciences of humanity” occupied contested terrain.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. Martin Shaw and Ian Miles, “The Social Roots of Statistical Knowledge,” Martin Shaw and Ian Miles, eds., Demystifying Social Statistics (London: Pluto Press, 1979), 31.

    Google Scholar 

  2. M.J. Cullen, The Statistical Movement in Early Victorian Britain: The Foundation of Empirical Social Research (New York: Barnes & Noble, 1975), 11.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Philip Abrams, The Origins of British Sociology: 1834–1914 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1968), 9.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Quoted in Viktor Hilts, “Aliis exterendum, or the Origins of the Statistics Society of London,” Isis 69, no.246 (March 1978): 27.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Mark Blaug, Ricardian Economics (Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1973), 15 and

    Google Scholar 

  6. Blaug A, Economic Theory in Retrospect (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1968), 667.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Theodore Porter, Rise of Statistical Thinking1820–1900 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1986), 27.

    Google Scholar 

  8. In general, those troubled by this issue also feared that too great a focus on empirical data would lead to a devaluing of the crucial importance of scientific theory and theoretical understanding. Lawrence Goldman, “The Origins of British Social Science: Political Economy, Natural Science and Statistics, 1830–1835,” Historical Journal6 (1983): 609.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Gerard Koot, English Historical Economics 1870–1926: The Rise of Economic History and Neomercantilism (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1987), 20.

    Google Scholar 

  10. M.V. Ptukha, Ocherki po istorii statistiki v SSSR (Moscow: Izd. Akademii nauk, 1959), 111,

    Google Scholar 

  11. and N.K. Karataev, Russkaia ekonomicheskaia mysl’ v period krizisa feodal’nogo khoziaistva (Moscow: Izd. Moskovskogo Universiteta, 1957), 72–74.

    Google Scholar 

  12. N.K Karataev, Ekonomicheskie nauki v Moskovskom universitete, 1755–1955 (Moscow: Izd. Moskovskogo Universiteta, 1956), 93.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See general discussion in Ulla Schafer, Historische Nationaloekonomie und Sozialstatistik als Gesellschaftswissenschaften (Vienna: Bohlau, 1971),

    Google Scholar 

  14. and G. Eisermann, Die Grundlagen des Historismus in der deutschen Nationaloekonomie (Stuttgart: F. Enke, 1956). Among the English-language scholarly works to address the economics methodenstreit in recent decades are

    Google Scholar 

  15. D.C. Coleman, History and the Economic Past: An Account of the Rise and Decline of Economic History (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1987),

    Google Scholar 

  16. and Alon Kadish, Historians, Economists and Economic History (New York: Routledge, 1989).

    Google Scholar 

  17. English-language studies of German historical economics are rare. See William Cherin, “The German Historical School of Economics: A Study in Methodology of the Social Sciences.” Ph.D. diss. (University of California at Berkeley, 1933) and Nicholas Balabkins, Not By Theory Alone: The Economics of Gustav von Schmoller and his Legacy to America (Berlin: Duncker and Humblot, 1988).

    Google Scholar 

  18. Although Verein economists shared a belief in the importance of what they called “the social question,” they differed markedly in their proposed solutions. See Dieter Lindenlaub, Richtungskampfe in Verein fur Sozialpolitik (Wiesbaden: F. Steiner, 1967),

    Google Scholar 

  19. Kenneth Barkin, The Controversy over German Industrialization 1880–1902 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1970), 138–147,

    Google Scholar 

  20. and Woodruff Smith, The Ideological Origins of Nazi Imperialism (New York: Oxford University Press, 1986), 21–30.

    Google Scholar 

  21. See B.N. Chicherin, “Die Leibeigenschaft in Russland,” Deutsche-Staats-worterbuch 6 (Stuttgart, 1861): 393–411

    Google Scholar 

  22. Quoted in S. Frederick Starr, Decentralization and Self Government in Russia, 1833–1870 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1972), 261.

    Google Scholar 

  23. S.M. Bleklov, Travaux statistique des zemstvo russe (Paris, 1893), 15.

    Google Scholar 

  24. Foreign observers like Emile de Laveleye, Paul Leroy-Beaulieu, the German scholar Christian Walcher, and the British journalist Donald Mackenzie Wallace criticized the Valuev Commission for the arbitrariness of its conclusions and its failure to invite direct peasant testimony. See discussion of Wallace’s view in Kingston-Mann, In Search 169–170 and the careful analysis of the Valuev investigations in Steven Grant, The Peasant Commune in Russian Thought, 1861–1905, Ph.D. diss. (Harvard, 1973), 192–272.

    Google Scholar 

  25. L.I. Kuchumova, “Iz istoriia obsledovaniia sel’skoi pozemel’noi obshchiny v 1887–1880 godakh,” Istoriia SSSR 3 (1978): 115–127.

    Google Scholar 

  26. I am indebted to Robert Johnson for his generous, long-ago sharing of biographical data on individual zemstvo statisticians. See Robert Johnson, “Liberal Professionals and Professional Liberals: The Zemstvo Statisticians and Their Work,” W.S. Vucinich and T. Emmons, eds., The Zemstvo in Russia: An Experiment in Local Self-government (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982), 343–363. An extremely valuable discussion that illuminates the relationship between zemstvo statistical findings and the expectations of the tsarist regime is

    Google Scholar 

  27. David Darrow, “The Politics of Numbers: Zemstvo Land Assessment and the Conceptualization of Russia’s Rural Economy,” Russian Review 59, no.1 (2000): 52–75. Useful surveys include

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. NA. Svavitskii, Zemskie podvornye perepisi:Obzor metodologii (Moscow: Gosstatizdat, 1961);

    Google Scholar 

  29. A.A. Kaufman, “The History and Development of Official Russian Statistics,” in John Koren, ed., The History of Statistics: Their Development and Progress in Many Countries (New York: Macmillan, 1918), 520–531;

    Google Scholar 

  30. and A.A. Rusov, Kratkii obzor razvitiia otsenochnoi statistiki (Kiev, 1913).

    Google Scholar 

  31. Belokonskii was himself a zemstvo statistician exiled to Siberia for his connection with the revolutionary organization Zemlia i Volia. See I.P Belokonskii, V gody bespraviia (Moscow: Izd. Vses. Ob-va Politkatorzhan i Ssyl’no-poselentsev, 1930), 43.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Kaufman made this argument in l894 at the Ninth Congress of Naturalists and Physicians. See Z.M. Svavitskaia, “Moskovskii universitet i zemskaia statistika,” Ocherki po istorii statistiki SSSR, 2 (Moscow: Izd. Akademii Nauk, 1957), 99, 101.

    Google Scholar 

  33. In Russia, the practices traditionally associated with the English commons were far more pronounced in the peasantry’s traditional, repartitional land communes. Although hereditary (podvornoe) tenure prevailed in the western regions of the Russian Empire and some parts of the south, the distinction between communal and podvornoe tenure was frequently problematic, because both usually featured the communal use of pasture and forest lands. See Steven Grant. Although hereditary (podvornoe) tenure prevailed in the western regions of the Russian Empire and some parts of the south, the distinction between communal and podvornoe tenure was frequently problematic, because both usually featured the communal use of pasture and forest lands. See Steven Grant, “Obshchina i Mir,” Slavic Review 35, no.4 (1976): 636–651.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. V.V. Veselovskii and Z.G. Frenkel, Iubileinyi zemskii sbornik (St. Petersburg: Izd. Popovoi, 1914), 346–348.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Vera Romanova Leikina-Svirskaia, Intelligentsiia v Rossii vo vtoroi polovine xix veka (Moscow: Mysl’, 1971), 209–210.

    Google Scholar 

  36. V.V. Veselovskii, Istoriia zemstva za 40 let (St. Petersburg: Izd. Popovoi, 1909–11), 1: 81–83.

    Google Scholar 

  37. I.P Belokonskii, Dan vremeni (Moscow: Zadruga, 1918), 79–80.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Z. Tverdova-Svavitskaia, Zemskie podvornye perepisi1880–1913 (Moscow: Ts.SU SSSR, 1926), 117–118. In Kherson province, research was suspended after zem-stvo statisticians revealed massive evidence of gentry tax evasion; see Robert Johnson, “Liberal Professionals,” 345–346, 353–354.

    Google Scholar 

  39. N.M. Astyrev, “K voprosu ob organizatsii tekushchei zemskoi statistiki,” Russkaia Mysl’ 5 (1887): 43–60; and Bleklov, Travaux statistique, 21–22.

    Google Scholar 

  40. See Chris Argyris, “Diagnosing Defenses against the Outsider,” in G. McCall and J.L. Simmons, eds., Issues in Participant Observation (New York: Random House, l969), 114–127,

    Google Scholar 

  41. See especially V.P Vorontsov, Progressivnye techeniia v krestianskom khoziaistve (St. Petersburg, 1892), 25–27.

    Google Scholar 

  42. See discussion in Esther Kingston-Mann, Lenin and the Problem of Marxist Peasant Revolution (New York: Oxford University Press, 1983), 48.

    Google Scholar 

  43. V.E. Postnikov, Iuzhno-russkoe krest’ianskoe khoziaistvo (Moscow: I.N. Kushnerev, 1891).

    Google Scholar 

  44. N.N. Chernenkov, K kharakteristike krest’ianskogo khoziaistva (Moscow: Russkoe Tovarichestvo, 1905). According to the statistician

    Google Scholar 

  45. K.R. Kachorovskii, Chernenkov was the first to focus on this cyclical process. See “The Russian Land Commune in History and Today,” Slavonic and East European Review 7, no.21 (1929): 565–576. In the late nineteenth century, N.A. Kablukov and A.V. Peshekhonov published research and analysis along similar lines, which foreshadowed the post-1905 work of A.V. Chaianov’s “Organization and Production School.”

    Google Scholar 

  46. It is worth noting as well that after 1917, the former Marxist economist M.I. Tugan Baranovskii came to agree with this analysis of the zemstvo statistical data. Osnovy politicheskoi ekonomii, 5th edition (Petrograd: Pravo, 1918), 188–192.

    Google Scholar 

  47. See Rchard Pipes, “Russian Marxism and Its Populist Background: The Late Nineteenth Century,” The Russian Review 19, no.4, (October, 1960): 316–377 and Struve: Liberal on the Left (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970), 85. For a perspective quite sympathetic to Lenin’s judgment on “populists” as anti-Western reactionaries, see the writings of

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Andrzej Walicki, and in particular, The Controversy over Capitalism: Studies in the Social Philosophy of the Russian Populists (Notre Dame: Notre Dame University Press, 1989), 2–3.

    Google Scholar 

  49. For tsarist Finance Minister Witte, capitalism represented the high point and culmination of Russia’s economic development. To Lenin and his supporters, capitalism represented an essential prerequisite for proletarian socialist revolution. See discussion in Kingston-Mann , “Deconstructing the Romance of the Bourgeoisie: A Russian Marxist Path Not Taken,” Review of International Political Economy 10, no.1 (2003): 102–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. David Macey, Government and Peasant in Russia, 1861–1906: The Prehistory of the Stolypin Reforms (DeKalb: Northern Illinois University Press, 1987), 37.

    Google Scholar 

  51. V.I. Lenin, Polnoe sobranie sochinenii, 5th edition (Moscow: Gos. Izd. Polit. Lit., 1971–1975), vol. 3, 7.

    Google Scholar 

  52. See, e.g., K.R. Kachorovskii, Bor’ba za zemliu (St. Petersburg: Tip. D. P. Veisborg, 1908), xlviii.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Copyright information

© 2005 Susan P. McCaffray and Michael Melancon

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kingston-Mann, E. (2005). Statistics, Social Science, and Social Justice: The Zemstvo Statisticians of Pre-Revolutionary Russia. In: McCaffray, S.P., Melancon, M. (eds) Russia in the European Context, 1789–1914. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781403982261_8

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/9781403982261_8

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, New York

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-349-53073-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4039-8226-1

  • eBook Packages: Palgrave History CollectionHistory (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics