Skip to main content

Shylock as Homo Sacer?: Mercantilist Fallacies and Subjective Demand in The Merchant of Venice

  • Chapter
Revisionist Shakespeare: Transitional Ideologies in Texts and Contexts
  • 36 Accesses

Abstract

The Merchant of Venice perhaps rivals King Lear as the Shakespearean play that has most often been interpreted as an allegory of economic transition. Typical transitional readings of Merchant posit an ideological opposition between two broadly defined economic modes of production, and then locate the principal characters along these ideological axes. In the most sophisticated, counterintuitive of such readings, Walter Cohen argues that Antonio, the usurious merchant-financier, is the “harbinger of modern capitalism,” while Shylock is a retrograde, neo-feudal figure: “marginal, diabolical, irrational, archaic, medieval.”1 More recently, John Drakakis has argued that Shylock contradictorily embodies seigneurial and capitalistic qualities: “Shylock looks both backwards and forwards in the play. It is this double perspective that obscures what we think of as the passage to modernity, since it both challenges and facilitates a secular teleology.”2 Eric Mallin has complicated things further, suggesting that Shylock’s capitalist ethos manifests itself in his ability to realize a Christian “plutocratic fantasy” of extravagant spending.3

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. Walter Cohen, “The Merchant of Venice and the Possibilities of Historical Criticism,” in New Casebooks: The Merchant of Venice, ed. Martin Coyle (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1998), 45–72.

    Google Scholar 

  2. John Drakakis, “‘Jew, Shylock is my name’: Speech Prefixes in The Merchant of Venice as Symptoms of the Early Modern,” in Shakespeare and Modernity: Early Modern to Millennium, ed. Hugh Grady (London: Routledge, 2000), 105–121.

    Google Scholar 

  3. For other interpretations that rely on transitional schemas or that find symptoms of a market economy in the play, see Michael Nerlich, Ideology of Adventure: Studies in Modern Consciousness, 1100–1750, vol. 1, trans. Ruth Crowley (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1987), chap. 7;

    Google Scholar 

  4. and Frederick Turner, Shakespeare’s Twenty-First Century Economics: The Morality of Love and Money (New York: Oxford University Press, 1999), chap. 5.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Eric Roll, A History of Economic Thought (London: Faber and Faber, 1938), 46.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Odd Langholm, Price and Value in the Aristotelian Tradition: A Study in Scholastic Economic Sources (Norwegian Research Council for Science and the Humanities, 1979), 32.

    Google Scholar 

  7. For an earlier critique of the theory of intrinsic value, see Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis (New York: Oxford University Press, 1954), 60–62.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Hannah Robie Sewall, The Theory of Value Before Adam Smith, in Publications of the American Economic Association, Third Series, vol. II, n. 3 (New York: Macmillan Company, 1901), 15.

    Google Scholar 

  9. On the relationship between labor and the just price see Lewis H. Haney, History of Economic Thought (New York: Macmillan Company, 1949), 99–100; Raymond de Roover, “The Concept of the Just Price: Theory and Economic Policy,” Journal of Economic History 18 (1958): 418–434; and Langholm, Price and Value, 61–84.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Karl Marx, Capital III (New York: International Publishers, 1967), 378

    Google Scholar 

  11. cited in Jon Elster, Making Sense of Marx (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985), 489. As Elster remarks, “Although the view that money might generate profit independently of production is indeed preposterous, it was the foundation of mercantilist reasoning for a long time. We find the seventeenth-century cameralists arguing that wars would never run an economy down so long as the money remained in the country, as if soldiers could be fed on gold and silver” (489).

    Google Scholar 

  12. Thomas Mun, England’s Treasure by Forraign Trade (London, 1663), 20, cited in Bruno Suviranta, The Theory of the Balance of Trade in England: A Study in Mercantilism (Helsingfors, 1923), 72–73.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Cited in Lars Magnusson, Mercantilism: The Shaping of an Economic Language (London: Routledge, 1994), 162. Bacon, though, was quick to point out, along with Machiavelli, that money is decidely not the sinews of war: “Neither is money the sinews of war (as it is trivially said), where the sinews of men’s arms, in base and effeminate people, are failing.”

    Book  Google Scholar 

  14. Francis Bacon, “Of the True Greatness of Kingdoms and Estates,” in Francis Bacon: The Essays, ed. and intro. John Pitcher (London: Pengin Books, 1985), 148.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Eli F. Heckscher, Mercantilism, 2 vols., trans. Mendel Shapiro (London: George Allen & Unwin, Ltd., 1935), 2: 138–139.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Henry Dunning Macleod, Principles of Economical Philosophy, 2 vols. (London: Longmans, Green, Reader, and Dyer, 1872–1875), 1: 50, cited in Suviranta, The Theory of the Balance of Trade, 115.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Adam Smith, An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of The Wealth of Nations, ed. Edwin Cannan (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1976), 4.1, 472, cited in Suviranta, The Theory of The Balance of Trade, 115.

    Google Scholar 

  18. All citations taken from William Shakespeare, The Merchant of Venice, ed. Brents Stirling (Baltimore, MD: Penguin Books, 1990). All citations are noted in text.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Richard Halpern, Shakespeare Among the Moderns (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1997), 190.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Bernard Grebanier, The Truth About Shylock (New York: Random House, 1962), 250–251.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Hugo Grotius, The Law of War and Peace, trans. Francis W. Kelsey (Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill, 1925), 2.12, 351.

    Google Scholar 

  22. I owe much of this summary of the usury debates to Norman Jones, God and the Moneylenders: Usury and Law in Early Modern England (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1989); and R.H. Tawney’s introduction to his edition of Thomas Wilson’s Discourse Upon Usury, intro. and ed. R.H. Tawney (New York: Harcourt, Brace and Co., 1925).

    Google Scholar 

  23. See also John T. Noonan, The Scholastic Analysis of Usury (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1957);

    Google Scholar 

  24. and Benjamin Nelson, The Idea of Usury (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1969).

    Google Scholar 

  25. C.L. Barber, Shakespeare’s Festive Comedy: A Study of Dramatic Form and its Relation to Social Custom (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1958), 168.

    Google Scholar 

  26. A.D. Moody, “The Letter of the Law,” in The Merchant of Venice: Critical Essay, ed. Thomas Wheeler (New York: Garland Publishing, 1991), 86.

    Google Scholar 

  27. René Girard, A Theater of Envy: William Shakespeare (New York: Oxford University Press, 1991), 246.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Giorgio Agamben, Homo Sacer: Sovereign Power and Bare Life, trans. Daniel Heller-Roazen (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1995), 82.

    Google Scholar 

  29. For a foundational essay on the role of New Testament morality in the play, see Barbara K. Lewalski, “Biblical Allusion and Allegory in The Merchant of Venice,” Shakespeare Quarterly 13 (1962): 327–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Karen Newman, “Portia’s Ring: Unruly Women and Structures of Exchange in The Merchant of Uenice,” Shakespeare Quarterly 38 (1987): 26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Claude Levi-Strauss, Introduction to the Work of Marcel Mauss, in The Logic of the Gift, ed. Alan Schrift (New York: Routledge, 1997), 55–56.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Northrop Frye, The Anatomy of Criticism: Four Essays (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1971), 162.

    Google Scholar 

  33. On the “two worlds” of comedy, see Elliot Krieger, A Marxist Study of Shakespeare’s Comedies (London: Macmillan Press, 1979), 1–7.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  34. Ernst Bloch, The Utopian Function of Art and Literature: Selected Essays, trans. Jack Zipes and Frank Mecklenburg (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996), 41.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Arthur O. Lovejoy, The Great Chain of Being: A Study of the History of an Idea (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1971), 3–23.

    Google Scholar 

  36. I owe much of my understanding of Lovejoy’s notion of the genesis of ideas to Michael Bristol’s excellent overview of Lovejoy’s study in Michael D. Bristol, Shakespeare’s America, America’s Shakespeare (London: Routledge, 1990), 145–151.

    Google Scholar 

  37. See Georges Bataille, “The Notion of Expenditure,” in Visions of Excess: Selected Writings, 1927–1939, trans. Allan Stoekl, with Carlo Lovitt and Donald M. Leslie, Jr. (Minneapolis: The University of Minnesota Press, 1985), 116–129.

    Google Scholar 

  38. For a critique of Bataille’s theory of expenditure, see Barbara Herrnstein Smith, Contingencies of Value: Alternative Perspective for Critical Theory (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1988), 134–149.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Copyright information

© 2004 Paul Cefalu

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Cefalu, P. (2004). Shylock as Homo Sacer?: Mercantilist Fallacies and Subjective Demand in The Merchant of Venice . In: Revisionist Shakespeare: Transitional Ideologies in Texts and Contexts. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781403973658_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics