Skip to main content

More Risk, Greater Wealth Inequality

  • Chapter
  • 224 Accesses

Abstract

The last three decades have been characterized by both rising wealth inequality and growing retirement income inadequacy, as a rising share of household s is expected to be unable to maintain its standard of living in retirement. At the same time, labor market risks—longer spells of unemployment and less stable earnings—and financial market risks—larger boom-and-bust cycles in the stock and housing markets—have gone up, too. And, as established in chapter 2, households have become more exposed to the potential fallout from these market risks.

How would you personally define what a secure retirement means to you?1

“I don’t believe in this world there is such a thing.” (White woman, 67 years old)

“I would like to be able to make a decent income on savings and have it completely secured.” (White woman, 74 years old)

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   50.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. For a summary of the basic portfolio theoretical arguments and some evidence, see Luigi Guiso, Tullio Jappelli, and Daniele Terlizzese, “Income Risk, Borrowing Constraints, and Portfolio Choice,” The American Economic Review 86, no. 1 (1996), 158–172;

    Google Scholar 

  2. Jason S. Seligman and Jeffrey B. Wenger, “Asynchronous Risk: Retirement Savings, Equity Markets, and Unemployment,” Journal of Pension Economics and Finance 5, no. 3 (2006), 237–255, doi: 10.1017/S1474747206002630;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Giuseppe Grande and Luigi Ventura, “Labor Income and Risky Assets under Market Incompleteness: Evidence from Italian Data,” Journal of Banking and Finance 26, no. 2 (2002), 597–620, doi:10.1016/S0378–4266(01)00236–9;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Miles S. Kimball, “Standard Risk Aversion,” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 61, no. 3 (1993): 589–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Also models of precautionary savings suggest that higher levels of labor market income uncertainty lead to increased savings (Jim Malley and Thomas Moutos, “Unemployment and Consumption,” Oxford Economic Papers 48, no. 4 [1996], 584–600;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Martha Starr-McCluer, “Health Insurance and Precautionary Savings,” The American Economic Review 86, no. 1 [1996], 285–295).

    Google Scholar 

  7. Models consider income uncertainty generated from both unemployment risk (Eric M. Engen and Jonathan Gruber, “Unemployment Insurance and Precautionary Saving,” Journal of Monetary Economics 47, no. 3 [2001], 545–579)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. and earnings volatility (Christopher D. Carroll, Karen E. Dynan, and Spencer D. Krane, “Unemployment Risk and Precautionary Wealth: Evidence from Households’ Balance Sheets,” Review of Economics and Statistics 85, no. 3 [2003], 586–604, doi:10.1162/003465303322369740) and find that households build up a buffer of savings to minimize consumption disruptions during unemployment.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. See Shlomo Bernartzi and Richard Thaler, “Heuristics and Biases in Retirement Savings Behavior,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 21, no. 3 (Summer 2007), 81–104 on the heuristics households use to make financial decisions in complex retirement savings.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Richard T. Campbell and Cathie Mayes Hudson, “Synthetic Cohorts from Panel Surveys: An Approach to Studying Rare Events,” Research on Aging 7, no. 1 (March 1985), 81–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. For a review of the relevant literature, see Stefano DellaVigna, “Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field,” Journal of Economic Literature 47, no. 2 (2009), 315–372, doi: 10.1257/jel.47.2.315. For the implications for household savings of systematic behavioral errors, see Bernartzi and Thaler, “Heuristics and Biases in Retirement Savings Behavior.”

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Remember that the underlying argument is that lower liquidity constraints theoretically should have made it easier for households to reallocate their risky and illiquid housing assets. Instead, households increasingly borrowed to finance consumption. Atif R. Mian and Amir Sufi, “House Prices, Home Equity-Based Borrowing, and the U.S. Household Leverage Crisis,” American Economic Review 101, no. 5 (2011), 2132–2156;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. David B. Gross and Nicholas S. Souleles, “Do Liquidity Constraints and Interest Rates Matter for Consumer Behavior? Evidence from Credit Card Data,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, no. 1 (2002), 149–185, doi: 10.1162/003355302753399472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Christian Weller and Derek Douglas, “One Nation Under Debt,” Challenge 50, no. 1 (February 2007), 54–74;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Christian Weller, “Need or Want: What Explains the Run-up in Consumer Debt?” Journal of Economic Issues 41, no. 2 (June 2007), 583–591.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Copyright information

© 2016 Christian E. Weller

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Weller, C.E. (2016). More Risk, Greater Wealth Inequality. In: Retirement on the Rocks. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137575142_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics