Skip to main content

Structural Imbalance

  • Chapter
  • 212 Accesses

Abstract

As previous chapters have explored, there is a growing structural imbalance in the world economy, which has at its core a fundamental misalignment between our exploitation of nature and the creation of economic wealth. One aspect of this misalignment is that rich and large emerging market economies become carbon-dependent, whereas the majority of low and middle-income countries are resource-dependent. Another is the increasing dependence on exploiting more natural resources, such as fossil fuels, minerals, forests and non-renewable material use. But the most dramatic declines in recent decades have been in ecological capital — ecosystems such as wetlands, coral reefs, grasslands and freshwater systems that also provide valuable goods and services to economies. In addition, with greenhouse gas emissions continuing to grow, the Earth’s ability to absorb these emissions is diminishing.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   29.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   40.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. Human capital may also be important for entrepreneurial success in an economy. See, for example, Jens M. Unger, et al. (2011) “Human Capital and Entrepreneurial Success: A Meta-analytical Review”, Journal of Business Venturing, 26: 341–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Much of the available information across countries of human capital investment is related to educational expenditures or levels of educational attainment. Ideally, one should also include health and training-related investments. However, measuring the latter contributions has proven to be fraught with difficulties and thus a challenge. See the Appendix to this chapter and the discussion in Gang Liu and Barbara Fraumeni (2014) “Human Capital Measurement: A Bird’s Eye View”, chapter 3 in United Nations University (UNU)-International Human Dimensions Programme (IHDP) on Global Environmental Change; and United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) (2014) Inclusive Wealth Report 2014. Measuring Progress Toward Sustainability. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 83–108.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Robert J. Barro and Jong Wha Lee (2013) “A New Data Set of Educational Attainment in the World, 1950–2010”, Journal of Development Economics, 104: 184–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. This tradition stems from the Hecksher- Ohlin, or factor proportions, theory of how the comparative advantage of a country’s production, and thus its trade, is determined. Early developments of this theory stressed strongly that the primary factors key to determining the factor intensity of production and trade were the immobile endowments of an economy. For example, see Paul A. Samuelson (1948) “International Trade and the Explanation of Factor Prices”, The Economic Journal, 58: 163–184, p. 164: “The present note attempts to throw light on the matter under the simplifying assumptions most suited to the Ohlin analysis: two regions, say Europe and America, each endowed with different proportions of two perfectly immobile factors of production, say land and labor.” Similarly, Harry G. Johnson (1957) “Factor Endowments, International Trade and Factor Prices”, The Manchester School, 25: 270–283, p. 271 states: “… on the production side, technology and the supply of factors of production in each country are given (the latter implying that factors are immobile between countries).”

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Adrian Wood (1994) “Give Hecksher and Ohlin a Chance!”, Welt wirtschaftliches Archiv. (Review of World Economy), 130: 20–49, 21–22. Note also that Samuelson (1948), op. cit., in his influential development of the factor proportions (Hecksher-Ohlin) theory of trade considered the “two perfectly immobile factors of production” to be “land and labor” and not capital.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. See Chapter 2, The global integration of financial markets and its impact on the mobility of capital investments has been documented in Maurice Obstfeld and Alan M. Taylor (2004) Global Capital Markets: Integration, Crisis and Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press;

    Book  Google Scholar 

  7. on more recent trends see also Thomas Piketty (2014) Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  8. For example, according to Jörg Mayer and Adrian Wood (2001) “South Asia’s Export Structure in a Comparative Perspective”, Oxford Development Studies, 29: 5–29, 7: “Both labour and skill are also internationally mobile to some extent. Only a small fraction of the world’s labour force is able to move among countries, but for some individual countries such mobility is important (and the remittances of their mobile workers are an important export). There is also a high degree of mobility among some of the world’s most skilled workers: those with the experience, know-how and contacts needed to produce and sell goods on world markets, which is what exporting is all about. As with capital, the international mobility of highly skilled workers means that their services can usually be obtained to develop the production of goods in which a country’s resources give it a comparative advantage, reinforcing the H-O pattern of trade. However, barriers to harnessing the skills of such workers — poor communications facilities or restrictions on direct foreign investment, for example — may impede the realization of a resource-based comparative advantage in particular countries and particular sectors.”

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. This relationship between the relative costs of inputs and the relative prices of goods is often referred to as the Stopler-Samuelson effect, after Wolfgang Stopler and Paul A. Samuelson (1941) “Protection and Real Wages”, Review of Economic Studies, 9: 58–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. For example, Gavin Wright and Jesse Czelusta (2004) “Why Economies Slow: The Myth of the Resource Curse”, Challenge, 47(2): 6–38, p. 10 describe the expansion of the minerals endowment of the United States in the late 19th and early 20th centuries in the following manner: “On closer examination, the abundance of American mineral resources should not be seen as merely a fortunate natural endowment. It is more appropriately understood as a form of collective learning, a return on large-scale investments in exploration, transportation, geological knowledge, and the technologies of mineral extraction, refining, and utilization… In direct contrast to the notion of mineral deposits as a nonrenewable ‘resource endowment’ in fixed supply, new deposits were continually discovered, and production of nearly all major minerals continued to rise well into the twentieth century — for the country as a whole, if not for every mining area considered separately.”

    Google Scholar 

  11. The importance of international mobility of financial and reproducible capital for expanding the amount of land and natural resource supplies available for use by a primary-product exporting small open economy has been shown in economic models developed by Ronald Findlay (1995) Factor Proportions, Trade, and Growth. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press;

    Google Scholar 

  12. and Ronald Findlay and Mats Lundahal (1994) “Natural Resources, ‘Vent-For-Surplus’, and the Staples Theory”, in G. Meier (ed.), From Classical Economics to Development Economics: Essays in Honor of Hla Myint. New York: St. Martin’s Press, pp. 68–93. In these models, the relative natural resource abundant, small and open economy can expand its natural capital by allocating more reproducible capital for this purpose. As the domestic and international capital markets are fully integrated, the rate of return on this capital must equal the world interest rate for financial assets. The implication is that the economy will continue to expand its supplies of natural capital until the point of the additional returns for investing reproducible capital for such expansion just equals the world interest rate. Until that point occurs, the returns to investing financial and reproducible capital in expanding natural capital supplies exceeds the opportunity cost of investment (as represented by the world market rate of interest), and thus it is worthwhile to expand the supply of land and natural capital through such financial and reproducible capital investment.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  13. Essentially, these models formalize the process of “frontier” (i.e., land and natural resource) expansion observed by Guido di Tella (1982) “The Economics of the Frontier”, in C. P. Kindleberger and G. di Tella (eds) Economics in the Long View. London: Macmillan, pp. 210–227. According to di Tella (1982, p. 212), realizing the potential economic gains from frontier expansion requires “a substantial migration of capital and people” to exploit the abundant land and resources, which can only occur if this exploitation results in a substantial “surplus”, or “abnormal” economic rent. This observation is the basis of di Tella’s disequilibrium abnormal rents hypothesis; i.e., since frontier expansion takes time, there must be “disequilibrium” periods in which abnormal rents (profits well in excess of costs) can be exploited to simulate further frontier investments. In other words, since frontier (i.e., natural capital) expansion takes time, there must be “disequilibrium” periods in which abnormal rents can be exploited to stimulate further frontier investments, and as a result, “the greater is the rent at the frontier the more intense will be the efforts to expand it, and the quicker will be the pace of expansion” (di Tella (1982), p. 217). It is this perspective on the role of investments in expanding natural capital supplies in relatively resource abundant economies that is also put forward here.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  14. See, for example, Edward B. Barbier (2011) Scarcity and Frontiers: How Economies Have Developed Through Natural Resource Exploitation. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press;

    Google Scholar 

  15. Ronald Findlay and Kevin H. O’Rourke (2007) Power and Plenty: Trade, War, and the World Economy in the Second Millennium. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press;

    Google Scholar 

  16. Gregg Huff (2007) “Globalization, Natural Resources, and Foreign Investment: A View from the Resource-rich Tropics.” Oxford Economic Papers, 59: i127–i155;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Eric L. Jones (1988) Growth Recurring: Economic Change in World History. Clarendon Press, Oxford.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Maurice Obstfeld and Alan M. Taylor (2004) Global Capital Markets: Integration, Crisis and Growth. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press;

    Book  Google Scholar 

  19. Patrick K. O’Brien (1997) “Intercontinental Trade and the Development of the Third World since the Industrial Revolution”, Journal of World History, 8(1): 75–133;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Kevin H. O’Rourke and Jeffrey G. Williamson (1999) Globalization and History: The Evolution of a Nineteenth-Century Atlantic Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press;

    Google Scholar 

  21. Lloyd G. Reynolds (1985) Economic Growth in the Third World, 1850–1980. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press;

    Google Scholar 

  22. John C. Weaver (2003) The Great Land Rush and the Making of the Modern World, 1650 –1900. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press;

    Google Scholar 

  23. Jeffrey G. Williamson (2006) Globalization and the Poor Periphery Before 1950. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  24. See, for example, Richard M. Auty (2001) Resource Abundance and Economic Development. Oxford: Clarendon Press;

    Google Scholar 

  25. Richard M. Auty (2007) “Natural Resources, Capital Accumulation and the Resource Curse”, Ecological Economics, 61(4): 600–610; Barbier (2011), op. cit., chapter 9;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Edward B. Barbier (2005) Natural Resources and Economic Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press;

    Book  Google Scholar 

  27. Kenneth M. Chomitz, with P. Buys, et al. (2007) At Loggerheads? Agricultural Expansion, Poverty Reduction, and Environment in the Tropical Forests. Washington DC: The World Bank;

    Google Scholar 

  28. Ian Coxhead and Sisira Jayasuriya (2003) The Open Economy and the Environment: Development, Trade and Resources in Asia. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar;

    Book  Google Scholar 

  29. Ronald Findlay and Mats Lundahl (1999) “Resource-Led Growth — A Long-Term Perspective: The Relevance of the 1870–1914. Experience for Today’s Developing Economies”, UNU/WIDER Working Paper No. 162. Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economics Research;

    Google Scholar 

  30. H. K. Gibbs, et al. (2010) “Tropical Forests were the Primary Sources of New Agricultural Lands in the 1980s and 1990s”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 107: 16732–16737;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Jonathon Isham, et al. (2005) “The Varieties of Resource Experience: Natural Resource Export Structures and the Political Economy of Economic Growth”, World Bank Economic Review, 19(2): 141–174;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Terry L. Karl (1997) The Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro-States. Berkeley: University of California Press;

    Google Scholar 

  33. Eric F. Lambin and Patrick Meyfroidt (2011) “Global Land Use Change, Economic Globalization, and the Looming Land Scarcity”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108: 3465–3472;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Thomas K. Rudel (2007) “Changing Agents of Deforestation: From State-initiated to Enterprise Driven Process, 1970–2000”, Land Use Policy, 24: 35–41;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. and Sven Wunder (2003) Oil Wealth and the Fate of the Forest: A Comparative Study of Eight Tropical Countries. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  36. This biased effect on production of an increase in supply in one factor endowment is often referred to as the Rybczynski effect after T. M. Rybczynski (1955) “Factor Endowments and Relative Commodity Prices”, Economica, 22: 336–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. See, for example, T. Aronsson and K.-G. Löfgren (1996) “Social accounting and welfare measurement in a growth model with human capital”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 98: 185–201;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Kenneth J. Arrow, et al. (2012) “Sustainability and the Measurement of Wealth”, Environment and Development Economics, 17: 317–353;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Partha S. Dasgupta (2009) “The Welfare Economic Theory of Green National Accounts”, Environmental and Resource Economics, 42: 3–38;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Kirk Hamilton and M. Clemens (1999) “Genuine savings rates in developing countries”, World Bank Economic Review, 13: 333–356;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. John M. Hartwick (1990) “Natural resources, national accounting and economic depreciation”, Journal of Public Economics, 43: 291–304;

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. and United Nations University (UNU)-International Human Dimensions Programme (IHDP) on Global Environmental Change and United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP) (2014) Inclusive Wealth Report 2014. Measuring Progress Toward Sustainability. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  43. This perspective on human capital is usually attributed to T. W. Schultz (1961) “Investment in Human Capital”, American Economic Review, 51: 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 2015 Edward B. Barbier

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Barbier, E.B. (2015). Structural Imbalance. In: Nature and Wealth. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137403391_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics