Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Palgrave Studies in the History of Finance ((PSHF))

  • 233 Accesses

Abstract

In October 1980 Margaret Thatcher rounded on the critics of her government’s economic strategy, proclaiming to the Conservative Party conference that ‘the lady’s not for turning’.3 Six months earlier, in line with monetarist prescriptions, her Chancellor, Sir Geoffrey Howe, had placed a series of declining money supply targets at the heart of economic policy, confidently asserting that ‘control of the money supply will over a period of years reduce the rate of inflation’, then running at nearly 20 per cent.4 By October, the money supply was overshooting its target range, inflation was still higher than when the Conservatives took office, and the British economy was in its deepest recession since the 1920s.5 With nominal interest rates at 16 per cent, the strong pound was pricing exports out of global markets.6 Britain would soon become a net importer of manufactured goods for the first time since before the Industrial Revolution. Unemployment was at levels not seen since the 1930s, and the Director-General of the Confederation of British Industry was threatening a ‘bare-knuckle fight’ with the government over economic policy.7 In 1980, monetarism was not working.

‘The supply of money’ — whatever that may be made to mean — is not by itself a reliable policy measure.

The Radcliffe Report, 1959.1

There would be no question of departing from the money supply policy, which is essential to the success of any anti-inflationary strategy.

Financial Statement and Budget Report, 1980.2

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. Thatcher admits that her conference speech was also directed towards the critics within her own Cabinet, M.H. Thatcher, The Downing Street Years (London, 1993), p. 122.

    Google Scholar 

  2. T.N. Beckett, ‘Director-General’s national conference speech 1980’, 11 November 1980, London, The National Archives (hereafter ‘TNA’), PREM 19/490.

    Google Scholar 

  3. A.J. Wiggins, ‘Note of a meeting held at 11 Downing Street’, 20 November 1980, TNA, T386/547.

    Google Scholar 

  4. J.A.H.L. Hoskyns, Just in Time: Inside the Thatcher Revolution (London, 2000), p. 263 and p. 269.

    Google Scholar 

  5. N. Lawson, The View from No. 11: Memoirs of a Tory Radical (London, 1992), p. 111.

    Google Scholar 

  6. A.J.C. Britton, Macroeconomic Policy in Britain, 1974–87 (Cambridge, 1991), p. 53.

    Google Scholar 

  7. The point is too frequently made that a money supply policy was ruled out while sterling was fixed under Bretton Woods. However, as Robert Mundell showed in the early 1960s, an independent monetary policy is theoretically compatible with a fixed exchange rate when there are capital controls and sufficient currency reserves. In practice, as both J.H.B. Tew and Peter Browning point out, the return to current account surplus after 1970 meant there was less strain on the reserves. This meant monetary policy could increasingly be directed towards the domestic economy, R.A. Mundell, ‘The appropriate use of monetary and fiscal policy for internal and external stability’, Staff Papers — International Monetary Fund, vol. 9, no. 1 (March, 1962), pp. 70–79; J.H.B. Tew, ‘Monetary policy: part I’, in F.T. Blackaby (ed.), British Economic Policy, 1960–74 (Cambridge, 1978), p. 239; P. Browning, The Treasury and Economic Policy, 1964–1985 (London, 1986), p. 276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. P.A. Hall, ‘The movement from Keynesianism to monetarism: institutional analysis and British economic policy in the 1970s’, in S. Steinmo, K.A. Thelen and F. Longstreth (eds), Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis (Cambridge, 1992), pp. 90–113; H. Pemberton, ‘Policy networks and policy learning: UK economic policy in the 1960s and 1970s’, Public Administration, vol. 78, no. 4 (Winter, 2000), pp. 771–92; M.J. Oliver and H. Pemberton, ‘Learning and change in 20th-century British economic policy’, Governance, vol. 17, no. 3 (July, 2004), pp. 415–41.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  9. D.E.W. Laidler, ‘Mayer on monetarism: comments from a British point of view’, in T. Mayer (ed.), The Structure of Monetarism (New York, 1978), p. 133.

    Google Scholar 

  10. D.E.W. Laidler, Monetarist Perspectives (Oxford, 1982), p. vii.

    Google Scholar 

  11. The principal architects of the Radcliffe Report were Alec (later Sir Alec) Cairncross, Professor R.L. Sayers, and Lord Radcliffe himself. Sayers outlined some of the academic theory behind the Radcliffe Report, in R.S. Sayers, ‘Monetary thought and monetary policy in England’, The Economic Journal, vol. 70, no. 280 (December, 1960), pp. 710–24. For a less technical approach from another committee member, see O.S. Franks, Some Reflections on Monetary Policy, in the Light of the Radcliffe Report (Bombay, 1960).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. M. Friedman, ‘The quantity theory of money — a restatement’, in M. Friedman (ed.), Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money (Chicago, 1956), pp. 3–21. The quantity theory has a long lineage, but mainly as an ‘equation of exchange’, for example, the Newcomb ‘transactions version’ popularised by Irving Fisher: MV = PT where M is the amount of money in circulation, V is the velocity of circulation, P is the price level, and T is an index of the aggregate transactions, M. Friedman, ‘Quantity theory of money’, in J. Eatwell, M. Milgate, and P. Newman (eds), Money (London, 1989), p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  13. This was essentially an application of capital theory to monetary theory. In this case capital extended beyond financial capital to include, for example, human capital. Harry Johnson called this ‘probably the most important development in monetary theory since Keynes’ General Theory’, H.G. Johnson, ‘Monetary theory and policy’, The American Economic Review, vol. 52, no. 3 (June, 1962), p. 350.

    Google Scholar 

  14. The signs below the arrows represent direction. For example, an increase in the stock of money in the Keynesian transmission mechanism results in a drop in interest rates, while an increase in investment leads to increased income, A.A. Walters, Money in Boom and Slump: An Empirical Inquiry into British Experience since the 1880s (London, 1971), p. 19.

    Google Scholar 

  15. T.G. Congdon, Keynes, the Keynesians and Monetarism (Cheltenham, 2007), pp. 149–50.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  16. Mundell, ‘The appropriate use of monetary and fiscal’, pp. 70–79; R.A. Mundell, ‘Capital mobility and stabilization policy under fixed and flexible exchange rates’, The Canadian Journal of Economic and Political Science, vol. 29, no. 4 (November, 1963), pp. 475–85; J.M. Fleming, ‘Domestic financial policies under fixed and floating exchange rates’, Staff PapersInternational Monetary Fund, vol. 9, no. 3 (November, 1962), pp. 369–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. R.J. Ball and T. Burns, ‘The inflationary mechanism in the UK’, The American Economic Review, vol. 66, no. 4 (September, 1976), pp. 467–84.

    Google Scholar 

  18. For an explanation of the key differences between the two, see J.J. Polak, ‘The two monetary approaches to the balance of payments: Keynesian and Johnsonian’, IMF Working Paper, WP/01/100 (August, 2001), pp. 1–25.

    Google Scholar 

  19. J.J. Polak, ‘Monetary analysis of income formation and payments problems’, Staff Papers — International Monetary Fund, vol. 6, no. 1 (November, 1957), pp. 1–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. In its earliest incarnation, DCE went further than Friedman by incorporating the ‘classical’ approach of a constant income velocity of circulation of ‘one’. Friedman and Schwartz estimated that it took 12–18 months for troughs and peaks in money supply growth to translate into troughs and peaks in economic activity, M. Friedman and A.J. Schwartz, ‘Money and business cycles’, The Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 45, no. 1, part 2, supplement (February, 1963), pp. 32–64; J.J. Polak and L. Boissoneault, ‘Monetary analysis of income and imports and its statistical operation’, Staff Papers — International Monetary Fund, vol. 7, no. 3 (April, 1960), pp. 349–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. F.H. Capie, The Bank of England: 1950s to 1979 (New York, 2010), p. 645.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  22. For this and other criticisms of Capie’s Bank of England, see G. Hacche, ‘The Bank of England 1950s to 1979’, Economica, vol. 80, no. 318 (April, 2013), pp. 372–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. M0 comprises the monetary liabilities of the Bank of England, coin issued by the Royal Mint, and the fiduciary note issue of the Scottish and Northern Irish banks; C.A.E. Goodhart, Monetary Theory and Practice: The UK Experience (London, 1984), p. 200. Chapter 6, ‘Analysis and the Determination of the Stock of Money’ was first presented in 1972, p. 16.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  24. While Quantitative Easing is certainly ‘monetary base creation’, it is far from clear that it is ‘monetary base control’. The Bundesbank abandoned a brief experiment with monetary base control in 1973 after it endangered the stability of the German banking system. The Swiss National Bank implemented monetary base control in November 1979 after suspending its M1 targets a year earlier because of the rapid appreciation of the Swiss franc. J. von Hagen, ‘Monetary targeting in Germany’, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 43, no. 3 (June, 1999), pp. 681–701; V.E. Argy, A. Brennan, and G. Stevens, ‘Monetary targeting: the international experience’, Economic Record, vol. 66, no. 1 (March, 1990), pp. 37–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. More recently, Tim Congdon has written ‘The monetary base is — and long has been — determined by what is happening in the economy; it does not determine what banks, the money stock or the economy will do in the future’, Congdon, Keynes, the Keynesians and monetarism, pp. 152–53; D.E.W. Laidler, ‘Review: Dow and Saville’s critique of monetary policy - a review essay’, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 27, no. 3 (September, 1989), pp. 1147–59.

    Google Scholar 

  26. W.A. Allen, ‘Recent developments in monetary control in the United Kingdom’, in L.H. Meyer (ed.), Improving Money Stock Control: Problems, Solutions, and Consequences (Boston MA., 1983), p. 104.

    Google Scholar 

  27. HM Treasury, ‘Report of money supply and inflation research group’, 9 December 1980, TNA, T388/195; I.D. Saville and K.L. Gardiner, ‘Stagflation in the UK since 1970: a model-based explanation’, National Institute Economic Review, vol. 117, no. 1 (August, 1986), pp. 52–69; Britton, Macroeconomic policy, pp. 272–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. D.E.W. Laidler and J.M. Parkin, ‘Inflation: a survey’, The Economic Journal, vol. 85, no. 340 (December, 1975), pp. 741–809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. This curious view is repeated by both Margaret Thatcher and Alan Walters. Capie, Bank of England, p. 6; Thatcher, Downing Street Years, p. 43; A.A. Walters, Britain’s Economic Renaissance: Margaret Thatcher’s Reforms 1979–1984 (Oxford, 1986), p. 77.

    Google Scholar 

  30. E. Nelson and K.O. Nikolov, ‘Monetary policy and stagflation in the UK’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 36, no. 3 (June, 2004), pp. 293–318; Batini and Nelson, The U.K.’s rocky road.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. E. Nelson and K.O. Nikolov, ‘UK inflation in the 1970s and 1980s: the role of output gap mismeasurement’, Journal of Economics and Business, vol. 55, no. 4 (July/August, 2003), pp. 353–70; A. Orphanides, ‘Monetary policy rules and the Great Inflation’, The American Economic Review, vol. 92, no. 2 (May, 2002), pp. 115–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. D.W.G. Wass, Decline to Fall: The Making of British Macro-economic Policy and the 1976 IMF Crisis (Oxford, 2008), p. 46.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  33. Goodhart, Monetary Theory, pp. 91–121. See also C.A.E. Goodhart, ‘The Bank of England over the last 35 years’, Bankhistorisches Archiv, Beih. 43, Welche Aufgaben muß eine Zentralbank wahrnehmen: historische Erfahrungen und europäische Perspektiven (Stuttgart, 2004), pp. 29–54.

    Google Scholar 

  34. C.A.E. Goodhart, ‘The Bank of England and the 1981 Budget’, in D.J. Needham and A.C. Hotson (eds), Expansionary Fiscal Contraction: the Thatcher Government’s 1981 Budget in Perspective (Cambridge, 2014).

    Google Scholar 

  35. D.H. Gowland, Controlling the Money Supply (London, 1982), pp. 94–96.

    Google Scholar 

  36. C.A.E. Goodhart and A.D. Crockett, ‘The importance of money’, BEQB, 10, 1970, pp. 159–98; L.D.D. Price, ‘The demand for money in the United Kingdom: a further investigation’, BEQB, 12, 1972, p. 43–55.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Goodhart, Monetary Theory, p. 96; C.A.E. Goodhart, ‘A central bank economist’, in P.D. Mizen (ed.), Central Banking, Monetary Theory and Practice (Cheltenham, 2003), p. 26.

    Google Scholar 

  38. J.C.R. Dow and I.D. Saville, A Critique of Monetary Policy: Theory and British Experience (Oxford, 1990).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  39. G. Hacche and C. Taylor (eds), Inside the Bank of England: Memoirs of Christopher Dow, Chief Economist 1973–84 (Basingstoke, 2013), p. 61–62.

    Google Scholar 

  40. C.J. Allsopp, ‘Macroeconomic policy: design and performance’, in M.J. Artis and D.P. Cobham (eds), Labour’s Economic Policies, 1974–1979 (Manchester, 1991), p. 30.

    Google Scholar 

  41. C. Gordon, The Cedar Story: The Night the City was Saved (London, 1993), p. 144.

    Google Scholar 

  42. M. Moran, The Politics of Banking: The Strange Case of Competition and Credit Control (London, 1986), p. 94.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  43. As the asset-price boom of 1972–73 came to an end, a number of secondary banks found themselves over-exposed to falling property prices. The Bank launched the ‘Lifeboat’ in December 1973 shortly after coordinating the individual rescues of London and County Securities and Cedar Holdings. At the peak of the crisis in March 1975, the Bank had arranged £2.3 billion of funding, largely from the clearing banks. Of the 26 financial institutions that were offered help, 8 were allowed to fail, ‘How the “Bankers’ Lifeboat” came to the rescue’, Financial Times, 29 January 1974; M.I. Reid, The Secondary Banking Crisis, 1973–75: Its Causes and Course (London, 1982); Capie, Bank of England, pp. 524–86; Gordon, The Cedar Story.

    Google Scholar 

  44. D.J.S. Hancock, ‘Note of a meeting between the Chancellor and the chairmen of the London clearing banks’, 12 September 1969, TNA, T326/964.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 2014 Duncan Needham

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Needham, D. (2014). Introduction. In: UK Monetary Policy from Devaluation to Thatcher, 1967–82. Palgrave Studies in the History of Finance. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137369543_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics