Skip to main content

Abstract

In June 1816, the British Parliament did something no one had ever done before: it officially introduced a gold standard. Until 1816, ‘money’ in Britain comprised a massively heterogeneous network of varying exchange practices and social conventions. It existed in a variety of forms: bullion, coins, tokens, bills of exchange, promissory notes, government bills, and banknotes. These were exchangeable in a number of different institutions: goldsmiths, shops, country and metropolitan banks, factories, and agencies. Forgery was a crime and a nuisance, but for many people it was also a way to facilitate commerce where sanctioned practices were inaccessible. Money also had social meanings. In early-modern times, money was conceived metaphorically as blood, food, animals, and birds. Money was life. It could also be death: ill-got riches were wounds; excessive debt was a disease. Francis Bacon once remarked that ‘money is dirt’ in both senses of the term, land and muck. Money was a means for people to calculate their social worth. It was a way to distinguish the rich from the poor, men and women, husbands and wives. Money could be given as a gift, received as a token of gratitude, held up as a pledge of honor, and hoarded as a form of rebellion. The ability to create money was a sign of ingenuity; destroying it meant power. Money was a means of escape and a mark of bondage, a charm and a curse, a ticket to ride and a prison sentence.2

For a hundred years the system worked, throughout Europe, with an extraordinary success and facilitated the growth of wealth on an unprecedented scale. To save and to invest became at once the duty and the delight of a large class. The savings were seldom drawn on and, accumulating at compound interest, made possible the material triumphs which we now all take for granted. The morals, the politics, the literature, and the religion of the age joined in a grand conspiracy for the promotion of saving. God and Mammon were reconciled. Peace on earth to men of good means. A rich man could, after all, enter the Kingdom of Heaven — if only he saved. A new harmony sounded from the celestial spheres.1

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. John Maynard Keynes,’ social Consequences of Changes in the Value of Money’, Essays in Persuasion. 1923. Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes Vol. 9 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1978), 62.

    Google Scholar 

  2. The’ social meaning of money’ has received a good deal of analysis from historians and sociologists. See especially Geoffrey Ingham, ‘On the Underdevelopment of the “Sociology of Money”’, Acta Sociologica 41 (1998): 3–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Deborah Valenze, The Social Life of Money in the English Past (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2006).

    Google Scholar 

  4. On the history of the gold standard and the rise of the British national currency see especially Eric Helleiner, The Making of National Money: Territorial Currencies in Historical Perspective (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2003), 19–121

    Google Scholar 

  5. Emily Gilbert and Eric Helleiner, eds., Nation-States and Money: The Past, Present, and Future of National Currencies (London: Routledge, 1999)

    Google Scholar 

  6. John E Chown, A History of Money from AD 800 (London: Routledge, 1994), 67–73

    Book  Google Scholar 

  7. John Kucich, Repression in Victorian Fiction: Charlotte Brontë, George Eliot, and Charles Dickens (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1987).

    Google Scholar 

  8. Lany Neal, ‘The Financial Crisis of 1825 and the Restructuring of the British Financial System’, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 80 (May/June 1998): 53–76

    Google Scholar 

  9. Michael D. Bordo, ‘Commentary’, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 81 (1998): 77–82.

    Google Scholar 

  10. On the response to the gold standard and its limitations see Karl Polanyi, The Great Transformation (Boston: Beacon, 1944)

    Google Scholar 

  11. Barry Eichengreen, Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996).

    Google Scholar 

  12. Matthew Rowlinson, Real Money and Romanticism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010), 33–56.

    Google Scholar 

  13. On the ‘traumatic’ prevalence of forgery in nineteenth-century fiction, see Sarah Malton, Forgery in Nineteenth-Century Literature and Culture: Fictions of Finance from Dickens to Wilde (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2009).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  14. To see how diverse monetary opinion in the Victorian era was, consult Mary Poovey ed., The Financial System in Nineteenth-Century Britain (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2003).

    Google Scholar 

  15. The most important book to make this claim, in its aesthetic context, is Barbara Hernstein Smith, Contingencies of Value: Alternative Perspectives for Critical Theory (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1988).

    Google Scholar 

  16. John L. Mackie, Ethics: Inventing Right and Wrong (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1977)

    Google Scholar 

  17. Julia Annas, ‘Moral Knowledge as Practical Knowledge’, Social Philosophy and Policy 18 (2001): 236–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Charles Taylor, Modern Social Imaginaries (Durham: Duke University Press, 2004), 12.

    Google Scholar 

  19. On the idea of intrinsic value in mercantilism see Andrea Finkelstein, Harmony and the Balance: An Intellectual History of Seventeenth-Century English Economic Thought (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2000), 41–4

    Google Scholar 

  20. Mary Poovey, A History of the Modern Fact (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1998), 66–91

    Book  Google Scholar 

  21. Jonathan Gil Harris, Sick Economies: Drama, Mercantilism, and Disease in Shakespeare’s England (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 2004), 6

    Google Scholar 

  22. Carl Wennerlind, ‘Credit-Money as the Philosopher’s Stone: Alchemy and the Coinage Problem in Seventeenth-Century England’, in Oeconomics in the Age of Newton, ed. Margarate Schabas and Neil De Marchi, History of Political Economy, Supplement 35 (2003): 238–9.

    Google Scholar 

  23. John Bender and David E. Wellbery, ‘Rhetoricality: On the Modernist Return of Rhetoric’, in The Ends of Rhetoric: History, Theory Practice, ed. John Bender and David E. Wellbery (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1990), 25.

    Google Scholar 

  24. The royal proclamations affecting the coinage can be found in Paul L. Hughes and James Francis Larkin, eds., Tudor Royal Proclamations (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1964–9).

    Google Scholar 

  25. On the history of the Royal Mint and its challenges see Sir John Craig, The Mint: A History of the London Mint from A.D. 287 to 1948 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1953)

    Google Scholar 

  26. Christopher Edgar Chaliss, ed., A New History of the Royal Mint (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992)

    Google Scholar 

  27. J. D. Gould, The Great Debasement: Currency and the Economy in Mid-Tudor England (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1970)

    Google Scholar 

  28. Thomas Sargeant and François R. Velde, The Big Problem of Small Change (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2002).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  29. The literature on these changes is extensive. Apart from P. G. M. Dickson’s The Financial Revolution: A Study of the Development of Public Credit, 1688–1756 (Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1967

    Google Scholar 

  30. Joyce Appelby, ‘Locke, Liberalism, and the Natural Law of Money’, Past and Present 71 (1976): 43–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. John Brewer, Sinews of Power: War, Money, and the English State: 1688–1783 (New York: Knopf, 1989)

    Google Scholar 

  32. Larry Neal, The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the Age of Reason (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990).

    Google Scholar 

  33. On bodily metaphors in eighteenth-century conversations about financial’ schemes’ and’ speculations’ see Peter de Bolla, The Discourse of the Sublime: Readings inHistory, Aesthetics, and the Subject(Oxford: Blackwell, 1989), 103–41

    Google Scholar 

  34. Catherine Ingrassia, Authorship, Commerce, and Gender in Early Eighteenth-Century England (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998), 17–39

    Google Scholar 

  35. Robert Mitchell, Sympathy and the State in the Romantic Era: Systems, State Finance, and the Shadows of Futurity (London: Routledge, 2007).

    Google Scholar 

  36. On bills of exchange see Ian Baucom, Specters of the Atlantic: Finance Capital, Slavery, and the Philosophy of History (Durham: Duke University Press, 2006), 44

    Google Scholar 

  37. On the ‘mediocrity’ of the Liverpool Administration, see Richard Brown, Church and State in Modern Britain, 1700–1850 (London: Routledge, 1991), 170–201.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  38. Boyd Hilton, Corn, Cash, and Commerce: The Economic Policies of the Tory Governments (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1977), 26–7.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Thomas De Quincey ‘Resumption of Cash Payments by the Bank of England’, Westmoreland Gazette, February 6, 1819, in Works of De Quincey, vol. 1, ed. Grevel Lindop (London: Pickering & Chatto, 2000–3), 337.

    Google Scholar 

  40. E. P. Thompson, The Making of the English Working Class (New York: Pantheon, 1963), 314–49.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Paul Delaney, Literature, Money, and the Market from Trollope to Amis (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2002).

    Google Scholar 

  42. Frances O’Gorman, ed., Victorian Literature and Finance (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007)

    Google Scholar 

  43. Deanna Kreisel, Economic Woman: Demand, Gender, and Narrative Closure in Eliot and Hardy (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 2011).

    Google Scholar 

  44. Cleanth Brooks, ‘Irony as a Principle of Structure’, in David Richter, ed., The Critical Tradition: Classic Texts and Contemporary Trends, 3rd edn. (Boston: Bedford/St. Martin’s Press, 2007), 799.

    Google Scholar 

  45. The crisis of representation in language has of course translated into post-structural interpretations of money. See especially Jacques Derrida, Given Time I: Counterfeit Money, trans. Peggy Kamuf (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994).

    Google Scholar 

  46. Michael Tratner, ‘Derrida’s Debt to Milton Friedman’, New Literary History 34 (2003): 791–806.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. See J. G. A. Pocock, The Machiavellian Moment: Florentine Political Thought and the Atlantic Republican Tradition (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1975, repr. 2003), 413–506

    Google Scholar 

  48. Liz Bellamy, Commerce, Morality, and the Eighteenth-Century Novel (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1998)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  49. Patrick Brantlinger, Fictions of State: Culture and Credit in Great Britain, 1694–1994 (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1996)

    Google Scholar 

  50. Catherine Gallagher, Nobody’s Story: The Vanishing Acts of Women Writers in the Marketplace, 1670–1820 (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1994)

    Google Scholar 

  51. Deirdre Shauna Lynch, The Economy of Character: Novels, Market Culture, and the Business of Inner Meaning (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1998)

    Google Scholar 

  52. Sandra Sherman, Finance and Fiction in the Eighteenth Century: Accounting for Defoe (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  53. Mary Poovey, Genres of the Credit Economy: Mediating Value in Eighteenth-and Nineteenth-Century Britain (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2008).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  54. James Chandler, England in 1819: The Politics of Literary Culture and the Case of Romantic Historicism (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1998), esp. 166–74.

    Google Scholar 

  55. Jane Austen in ‘New Historicism, New Austen, New Romanticism’, in Romanticism, History, Historicism: Essays on an Orthodoxy, ed. Damien Walford Davies (London: Routledge, 2009), 182–203.

    Google Scholar 

  56. Mark Osteen and Martha Woodmansee, ‘Taking Account of the New Economic Criticism: An Historical Introduction’, in The New Economic Criticism, ed. Osteen and Woodmansee (London: Routledge, 1999), 3–50.

    Google Scholar 

  57. Andrew Elfenbein, Romanticism and the Rise of English (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2009)

    Google Scholar 

  58. Ian Hunter, Culture and Government: The Emergence of Literary Education (Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1988)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  59. Robert Crawford, Devolving English Literature (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1992).

    Google Scholar 

  60. Quoted in Carl Wennerlind, ‘Money Talks, But What is it Saying? Semiotics of Money and Social Control’, Journal of Economic Issues 35 (2001): 557–74 (560).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  61. Alan W. Dyer, ‘Making Semiotic Sense of Money as a Medium of Exchange’, Journal of Economic Issues 23 (1989): 503–10.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  62. Margot C. Finn, The Character of Credit: Personal Debt in English Culture, 1740–1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003)

    Google Scholar 

  63. Craig Muldrew, The Economy of Obligation: The Culture of Credit and Social Relations in Early Modem England (Basingstoke: Macmillan, 1998)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  64. William St. Clair, The Reading Nation in the Romantic Period (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2007)

    Google Scholar 

  65. Clifford Siskin, The Work of Writing: Literature and Social Change in Britain, 1700–1830 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1999), 11

    Google Scholar 

  66. Raymond Williams, ‘Means of Communication as Means of Production’, in Problems in Materialism and Culture: Selected Essays (London: New Left Books, 1980), 50–63

    Google Scholar 

  67. John Feather, A History of British Publishing (London: Routledge, 1988).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  68. Marcus Wood, Radical Satire and Print Culture, 1790–1832 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1994), 55.

    Google Scholar 

  69. Kevin Gilmartin, Print Politics: The Press and Radical Opposition in Early Nineteenth-Century England (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996)

    Google Scholar 

  70. Paul Keen, The Crisis of Literature in the 1790s Print Culture and the Public Sphere (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  71. Siskin, Work of Writing, 140–52; Jon Klancher, The Making of English Reading Audiences, 1790–1832 (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1987).

    Google Scholar 

  72. ‘This ideal of authenticity becomes crucial owing to a development that occurs after Rousseau... that each of us has an original way of being human: each person has his or her own “measure”.’ Charles Taylor, ‘The Politics of Recognition’, in Multiculturalism: Examining the Politics of Recognition, ed. Amy Gutman (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994), 25–74 (30).

    Google Scholar 

  73. Phillip Connell, Romanticism, Economics, and the Question of ‘Culture’ (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001)

    Google Scholar 

  74. Catherine Gallagher, The Body Electric: Life, Death, and Sensation in Political Economy and the Victorian Novel (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2006)

    Google Scholar 

  75. Maureen McLane, Romanticism and the Human Sciences: Poetry, Population, and the Discourse of the Species (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  76. The fundamentals are laid out in Brian Massumi, Parables for the Virtual: Movement, Affect, Sensation (Durham: Duke University Press, 2002)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  77. Eve Kosofsky Sedgwick, Touching Feeling: Affect, Pedagogy, Performance (Durham: Duke University Press, 2003).

    Google Scholar 

  78. Andrea Henderson, Romanticism and the Painful Pleasures of Modern Life (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008).

    Google Scholar 

  79. Ian Baucom, Specters of the Atlantic: Finance Capital, Slavery, and the Philosophy of History (Durham: Duke University Press, 2006).

    Google Scholar 

  80. Robert Mitchell, Sympathy and the State in the Romantic Era: Systems, State Finance, and the Shadows of Futurity (London: Routledge, 2007).

    Google Scholar 

  81. Henry Thornton, An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of Great Britain (London: Hatchard, 1802), 13.

    Google Scholar 

  82. Sir James Steuart, An Inquiry into the Principles of Political Economy (1767), ed. Andrew. S. Skinner, Noboru Kobayashi, and Hiroshi Mizuta (London: Pickering & Chatto, 1998).

    Google Scholar 

  83. Goffman’s book on the way people manage affects for the sake of self-presentation is The Presentation of Self in Everyday Life (New York: Anchor, 1959). But his theory of embarrassment, which in fact complicates his general view, was outlined three years earlier in ‘Embanassment and Social Organization’, American Journal of Sociology 62 (1956): 264–71. See also W. Crozier, ed., Shyness and Embarrassment: Perspectives from Social Psychology (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990).

    Google Scholar 

  84. Eve Kosofsky Sedgwick and Adam Frank, ‘Shame in the Cybernetic Fold: Reading Silvan Tomkins’, in Shame and Its Sisters: A Silvan Tomkins Reader, ed. Sedgwick and Frank (Durham: Duke University Press, 1995), 1–28 (22).

    Google Scholar 

  85. Martha Nussbaum, Upheavals of Thought: The Intelligence of Emotions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003), 22.

    Google Scholar 

  86. Charles Altieri, The Particulars of Rapture: An Aesthetics of Emotion (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2003), 154

    Google Scholar 

  87. Thomas Pfau, Romantic Moods: Paranoia, Trauma, and Melancholy, 1790–1840 (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2005), 31.

    Google Scholar 

  88. Anthony Giddens, The Consequences of Modernity (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1990), 38.

    Google Scholar 

  89. On the scientific elements of Ricardo’s political economy see Margaret Schabas, The Natural Origins of Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2005), 112–19.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  90. According to Claudia Klaver, A/Moral Economics: Classical Political Economy and Cultural Authority in Nineteenth-Century England (Columbus: Ohio State University Press, 2002), 19.

    Google Scholar 

  91. David Ricardo, The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, in The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, ed. Piero Sraffa (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1951–73), 1

    Google Scholar 

  92. Teny Eagleton, The Ideology of the Aesthetic (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1990), 38.

    Google Scholar 

  93. Colin Nicholson, Writing and the Rise of Finance: Capital Satires of the Early Eighteenth Century (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994), 30.

    Google Scholar 

  94. Peter de Bolla, The Discourse of the Sublime: Readings in History, Aesthetics, and the Subject (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1989).

    Google Scholar 

  95. G. Gabrielle Stan, ‘Ethics, Meaning, and the Work of Beauty’, Eighteenth-Century Studies 35 (2002): 361–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  96. David Hume, Essays Moral, Political, and Literary, ed. Eugene F. Miller (Indianapolis: Liberty, 1986).

    Google Scholar 

  97. Adam Smith, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, ed. R. H. Campbell and A. S. Skinner (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1976), 53–64.

    Google Scholar 

  98. Dugald Stewart, ‘The Life and Writings of Adam Smith’, in Volume 11 of The Collected Writings of Dugald Stewart, ed. William Hamilton (Edinburgh: Constable, 1854–60), 62–3.

    Google Scholar 

  99. The first price currents and ‘exchange rate currents’ documenting the relative prices of European currencies were published in Antwerp in the 1540s and migrated to Amsterdam in the seventeenth century. See John J. McCusker, ‘The Demise of Distance: The Business Press and the Origins of the Information Revolution in the Early Modern Atlantic World’, American Historical Review 110 (2005): 295–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  100. See Daniel A. Rabuzzi, ‘Eighteenth-Century Commercial Mentalities as Reflected and Projected in Business Handbooks’, Eighteenth-Century Studies 29 (2005): 169–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  101. See Gillian Russell, ‘“Faro’s Daughters”: Female Gamesters, Politics, and the Discourse of Finance in 1790s Britain’, Eighteenth-Century Studies 33 (2000): 481–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  102. John Keats, Complete Poems, ed. Jack Stillinger (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1978), 34.

    Google Scholar 

  103. The gold of the first line has been thought by some critics to refer to the gold leaf that more important, and thus more expensive books in Keats’ time were inlaid with on their covers. Carl L. Johnson, ‘The Realms of Gold’, Keats-Shelley Journal 9 (1960): 6–10.

    Google Scholar 

  104. Lewis M. Schwartz, ‘Keats’ Critical Reception in Newspapers of his Day’, Keats-Shelley Journal 21–2 (1972–3): 37–52.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 2013 Alexander Dick

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Dick, A. (2013). Realms of Gold. In: Romanticism and the Gold Standard. Palgrave Studies in the Enlightenment, Romanticism and Cultures of Print. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137292926_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics