Skip to main content

Theoretical and Conceptual Foundations of Development Planning

  • Chapter
  • 77 Accesses

Abstract

The concepts of economic development and development planning in Nigeria were suffused with the philosophy of Eurocentric diffusionism through modernization. Modernization became influential in Nigeria’s development trajectory from the late colonial period when the American version of modernization became hegemonic . A significant component of modernization was the devaluation and denigration of indigenous Nigerian cultures along with the simultaneous promotion of the Euro-American culture as the epitome of civilization that non-Western cultures should strive to attain. This notion, under the concept of “pattern variables,” promoted the dichotomous idea of a hierarchy of cultures under which the Euro-American culture was at the peak and the Nigerian and other African cultures at the lowest level.1 Nigerian indigenous cultures were described as primitive, backward, barbaric, and cannibalistic and, therefore, incapable of sustaining any meaningful development. The European conquest of Nigerian societies was portrayed as a benevolent act meant to save Nigerians from themselves and civilize them as epitomized by the concept of “the civilizing mission.” But as has been demonstrated by orientalist scholars and other critics of Eurocentrism in the Third World, this myth of the civilizing mission was merely used to mask the European imperialist mission of exploitation and domination.2

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. See E. Said, Orientalism, New York: Random House, 1978; idem., Culture and Imperialism, London: Chatto and Windus, 1993; Dibua, “Eurocentrism,” and Amin, Eurocentrism.

    Google Scholar 

  2. M. P. Cowen and R. W. Shenton, Doctrines of Development, London and New York: Routledge, 1996, 5.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  3. K. Staudt, Managing Development: State, Society, and International Contexts, Newbury Park, CA: Sage, 1991.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  4. B. Okun and R. W. Richardson eds., Studies in Economic Development, New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1961, 230.

    Google Scholar 

  5. O. Nnoli, “Development/Underdevelopment: Is Nigeria Developing?,” in O. Nnoli ed., Path to Nigerian Development, Dakar: CODESRIA, 1981, 35–36.

    Google Scholar 

  6. B. Onimode, Imperialism and Underdevelopment in Nigeria, London: Macmillan, 1983;

    Google Scholar 

  7. W. Rodney, How Europe Underdeveloped Africa, Washington, D.C.: Howard University Press, 1982;

    Google Scholar 

  8. and D. A. Offiong, Imperialism and Dependency, Washington, D.C.: Howard University Press, 1982.

    Google Scholar 

  9. V. W. Ruttan, “What Happened to Political Development?,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 39, No. 2, 1991, 266–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. B. I. Adelman, Theories of Economic Growth and Development, Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1974, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  11. R. O. Ekundare, An Economic History of Nigeria, London: Methuen, 1974, 400.

    Google Scholar 

  12. See Offiong, Imperialism and Dependency, 39–44; T. Mkandawire, “The Crisis in Economic Development Theory,” Africa Development, Vol. XV, Nos. 3 and 4, 1990, 212;

    Google Scholar 

  13. W. W. Rostow, “Development: The Political Economy of the Marshallian Long Period,” in D. Meier and D. Seers eds., Pioneers in Development, Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1988;

    Google Scholar 

  14. and G. Rosen, Western Economists and Eastern Societies, Baltimore, MD: John Hopkins University Press, 1985.

    Google Scholar 

  15. The work of Paul Baran provided the initial theoretical foundation for the structuralist critique of the kind of developmentalism promoted by development economists. See P. Baran, The Political Economy of Growth, New York: Monthly Review Press, 1957. However, this approach was refined and popularized by Andre Gunder Frank, whose work greatly influenced the works of those who applied the dependency and underdevelopment perspective to Africa.

    Google Scholar 

  16. See A. G. Frank, Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America, New York: Monthly Review Press, 1969. For some of the works that applied this perspective to Africa, see Rodney, How Europe Underdeveloped Africa,

    Google Scholar 

  17. S. Amin, Accumulation on a World Scale, 2 Vols., New York: Monthly Review Press, 1974; and idem., Imperialism and Unequal Development, Sussex: Harvester Press, 1978. I. Wallerstein popularized the world system analysis.

    Google Scholar 

  18. See I. Wallerstein, “World System Analysis: Theoretical and Interpretative Issues,” in B. Hockey-Kaplan ed., Social Change in the Capitalist World Economy, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, 1978; and idem., The Capitalist World Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1979. For a comprehensive application of this approach to the Nigerian experience, see Onimode, Imperialism and Underdevelopment in Nigeria.

    Google Scholar 

  19. B. A. Olopoenia, “On the Meaning of Economic Development,” in I. Osayinwese ed., Development Economics and Planning: Essays in Honour of Ojetunji Aboyade, Ibadan, Nigeria: Unibadan Publishing Consultants, 1983, 22–23.

    Google Scholar 

  20. H. W. Arndt, “The ‘Trickle-Down’ Myth,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 32, No. 1, 1983, 1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. M. Finnemore, “Redefining Development at the World Bank,” in F. Cooper and R. Packard eds., International Development and the Social Sciences, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1997, 203–227.

    Google Scholar 

  22. H. Chenery et al., Redistribution with Growth, New York: Oxford University Press, 1974;

    Google Scholar 

  23. M. S. Ahluwalia and N. G. Carter, “Growth and Poverty in Developing Countries,” in H. Chenery ed., Structural Change and Development Policy, New York: Oxford University Press, 1979;

    Google Scholar 

  24. and M. A. Seligman ed., The Gap Between the Rich and the Poor, Boulder, CO: Westview, 1984.

    Google Scholar 

  25. International Labor Office, First Things First: Meeting the Basic Needs of the People of Nigeria, Addis Ababa: Jobs and Skills Program for Africa, 1981.

    Google Scholar 

  26. B. Wisner, Power and Need in Africa: Basic Human Needs and Development Policies, London: Earthscan, 1988;

    Google Scholar 

  27. F. Stewart, Planning to Meet Basic Needs, London: Macmillan, 1985;

    Google Scholar 

  28. and M. B. Brown, Africa’s Choices: After Thirty Years of the World Bank, Boulder, CO: Westview, 1996, 60.

    Google Scholar 

  29. See R L. Sklar, “The New Modernization,” Issue, Vol. 23, No. 1, 1995, 19–20; Ruttan, “What Happened to Political Development?,” 272–273; and Mkandawire, “The Crisis in Economic Development,” 223–225.

    Google Scholar 

  30. P. Evans, “Class, State, and Dependence in East Asia: Lessons for Latin Americanists,” in F. C. Deyo ed., The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialization, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1987, 203–226. Evans argued that rather than rendering dependency irrelevant, the East Asian experience provides very important grounds for a more robust dependency theory.

    Google Scholar 

  31. J. M. Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, New York: Harcourt Brace, 1936.

    Google Scholar 

  32. A. Hirshman, “The Rise and Decline of Development Economics,” in A. Hirshman, Essays in Trespassing: Economics to Politics and Beyond, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981;

    Google Scholar 

  33. and D. Seers, “The Birth, Life and Death of Development Economics,” Development and Change, Vol. 10, No. 4, 1979, 707–719. Mkandawire has pointed out that it is wrong to trace the ideological basis of development economics to Keynesianism and that although both shared a common critical approach to the neoclassical belief in the efficacy of market forces, the context of the two were totally different. Mkandawire, “The Crisis in Economic Development Theory,” 213–214. There is, however, an important sense in which it can be argued that development economists shared the theoretical assumptions of Keynesianism and that their association with Keynesianism greatly helped accord them a great amount of prestige in the 1950s and 1960s.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. P. Krugman, “Toward a Counter-Counterrevolution in Development Theory,” in Proceedings of the World Bank Conference on Development Economics, Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, 1992.

    Google Scholar 

  35. J. I. Dibua, “Economic Crisis and Structural Adjustment Programs,” in T. Falola ed., Africa: Volume 5: Contemporary Africa, Durham, NC: Carolina Academic Press, 2003; idem., “Devaluation and Economic Crisis: A Political Economy Analysis,” in A. Oyebade ed., The Transformation of Nigeria: Essays in Honor of Toyin Falola, Trenton, NJ: Africa World Press, 2002, 261–288; idem., “World Bank, International Monetary Fund, and Structural Adjustment,” in K. Shillington ed., Encyclopedia of African History, Vol. 3, New York and London: Fitzroy Dearborn, 2005, 1664–1666;

    Google Scholar 

  36. and B. Founou-Tchuigoua, “Africa Confronted With the Ravages of Neo-liberalism,” Africa Development, Vol. 21, Nos. 2 and 3, 1996, 5–24.

    Google Scholar 

  37. See World Bank, Sub-Saharan Africa: From Crisis to Sustainable Growth: A Long-Term Perspective Study, Washington, D.C.: The World Bank, 1989. Also see idem., Adjustment in Africa: Reforms, Results and the Road Ahead, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1994.

    Google Scholar 

  38. R. H. Green, “The IMF and the World Bank in Africa: How Much Learning?,” in T. M. Callaghy and J. Ravenhill, eds., Hemmed In: Responses to Africa’s Economic Decline, New York: Columbia University Press, 1993, 54–89.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Apart from criticism from African scholars and civil societies, the influential United Nations organ, the Economic Commission for Africa (ECA) published a report in which it harshly criticized SAP. The report went on to recommend issues such as popular participation in the political and economic affairs of African countries, rural and grassroots empowerment, subsidies for important social sectors that affect the lives of the majority of African peoples, state intervention in African economies, and the development of African alternatives to the adjustment programs. See Economic Commission for Africa (ECA), African Alternative Framework to Structural Adjustment Programme for Economic Recovery and Transformation (AAF-SAP), Addis Ababa: United Nations Economic Commission for Africa, 1989. It has been claimed that the World Bank’s attempts at addressing issues like popular participation, grassroots empowerment, and the development of rural areas was partly aimed at undercutting the criticisms of the ECA. Indeed the World Bank rushed to publish a report (Africa’s Adjustment and Growth in the 1980s) at the same time that the ECA was presenting its draft to a meeting of African finance ministers in Malawi. See C. Lancaster, “Economic Reform in Africa: Is it Working?,” in O. Obasanjo and H. d’Orville eds., The Leadership Challenge of Economic Reforms in Africa, New York: Crane Russak, 1991, 100–101. The publication of the long-term perspective study was the culmination of this exercise of preempting and undermining serious and credible criticism of SAP from within Africa.

    Google Scholar 

  40. J. I. Dibua, “Journey to Nowhere: Neo-Liberalism and Africa’s Development Crisis,” Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East, Vol. XVIII, No. 2, 1998, 119–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. A. Soyibo, “The Framework for Planning: Rationale and Methodology,” in Osayimwese ed., Development Economics and Planning, 96–97; and J. Clifford and G. Osmond, World Development Handbook, London: Charles Knight and Co., 1971, 36.

    Google Scholar 

  42. P. N. C. Okigbo, National Development Planning in Nigeria 1900–92, London, Portsmouth, NH, and Enugu, Nigeria: James Currey, Heinemann and Fourth Dimension, 1989, 37.

    Google Scholar 

  43. O. Iyanda, “Development Planning in Nigeria: Lessons From Experience,” The Guardian (Lagos, Nigeria), 25 November, 1985, 21.

    Google Scholar 

  44. B. Higgins et al., “Political Dimensions and Planning,” in P. Lengyel ed., Approaches to the Science of Socio-Economic Development, Paris: UNESCO, 1971, 344.

    Google Scholar 

  45. J. Waterbury, Exposed to Innumerable Delusions: Public Enterprise and State Power in Egypt, India, Mexico, and Turkey, New York: Cambridge University Press, 1993, 109.

    Google Scholar 

  46. E. Toyo, “Is Our Economy Planned?,” The Nigerian Economist, Vol. 1, No. 8, 1988, 10;

    Google Scholar 

  47. and L. Y. Berri ed., Planning a Socialist Economy, Vol. 1, Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1977, 26–27.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Also see P. N. C. Okigbo, “Economic Planning in Nigeria Since 1960,” in M. O. Kayode and Y. B. Usman, eds., Proceedings of the National Conference on Nigeria Since Independence, Zaria, March 1983, Vol. 2, Zaria, Nigeria: Gaskiya Corporation, 1985, 84.

    Google Scholar 

  49. See Toyo, “Is Our Econo Planned?,” 10; Berri ed., Planning a Socialist Economy, 26–31; and F. Archibugi et al., “Planning for Development,” in S. Holland ed., Beyond Capitalist Planning, Oxford: Basil Blackwell and Mott, 1978, 184–199.

    Google Scholar 

  50. B. Onimode, “Planning for Underdevelopment in Nigeria,” in Nnoli, ed., Path to Nigerian Development, 137–150; idem., “A Critique of Planning Concepts and Methodology in Nigeria,” Review of Black Political Economy, Vol. 7, No. 3, 1977, 296–308; and O. Oni, “A Critique of Development Planning in Nigeria,” Review of African Political Economy, No. 4, 1975, 87–93.

    Google Scholar 

  51. T. Falola and J. Ihonvbere, The Rise and Fall of Nigeria’s Second Republic: 1979–84, London: Zed Books, 1985, 3.

    Google Scholar 

  52. J. F. Ade Ajayi, The Past in the Present: The Factor of Tradition in Development, Lagos, Nigeria: Nigerian Institute of International Affairs, 1990, 12.

    Google Scholar 

  53. See Nigerian Economic Society, Perspective Planning for Nigeria: Proceedings of the Nigerian Economic Society Annual Conference, Lagos, May 16–19, 1989, Ibadan, Nigeria: Nigerian Economic Society, 1989.

    Google Scholar 

  54. J. Dibua, “Collapse of Purpose: Ibrahim Babangida, 1985–1993,” in L. A. Nwachuku and G. N. Uzoigwe eds., Troubled Journey: Nigeria Since the Civil War, Lanham, MD: University Press of America, 2004, 207–235.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Copyright information

© 2013 Jeremiah I. Dibua

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Dibua, J.I. (2013). Theoretical and Conceptual Foundations of Development Planning. In: Development and Diffusionism. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137286659_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137286659_2

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, New York

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-349-44938-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-137-28665-9

  • eBook Packages: Palgrave History CollectionHistory (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics