Skip to main content

Peasants’ Moral Economy and Implications for Russia’s Agrarian Capitalism

  • Chapter
The Moral Economy Reconsidered
  • 26 Accesses

Abstract

One of the key variables affecting societal change is the strength of embedded values. For rural societies and populations, the dominant analytical model since the mid-1970s has been the peasants’ moral economy. The moral economy approach sees values as “embedded” in peasant societies, and these values are therefore reflected in the nature of village institutions. Commercialization of agriculture disembeds peasant values and behavior, and displaces existing village institutions with market-based institutions.1 During commercialization, personal networks are replaced with impersonal networks, thereby depriving peasants of the “flexibility” inherent to traditional economies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. See William James Booth, “On the Idea of the Moral Economy,” American Political Science Review, vol. 88, no. 3 (September 1994), pp. 653–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. See e.g., Carol Scott Leonard, “Rational Resistance to Land Privatization: The Response of Rural Producers to Agrarian Reforms in Pre- and Post-Soviet Russia,” Post-Soviet Geography and Economics, vol. 41, no. 8 (November–December 2000), pp. 605–20.

    Google Scholar 

  3. For an elaboration of this argument, see Stephen K. Wegren, Agriculture and the State in Soviet and Post-Soviet Russia (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1998).

    Google Scholar 

  4. Jerry Hough sees a strong Russian state in the economy in general. See Jerry F. Hough, The Logic of Economic Reform in Russia (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 2001), chap. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  5. See Stephen K. Wegren, ed., Russia’s Policy Challenges: Security, Stability, and Development (Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, 2003);

    Google Scholar 

  6. and Dale R Herspring, ed., Putin’s Russia: Past Imperfect, Future Uncertain, 2nd ed. (Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield, 2004).

    Google Scholar 

  7. See Marshall I. Goldman, Gorbachev’s Challenge (New York: W. W. Norton, 1987), chap. 3;

    Google Scholar 

  8. Padma Desai, Perestroika in Perspective: The Design and Dilemmas of Soviet Reform (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989), esp. chap. 8;

    Google Scholar 

  9. and Archie Brown, The Gorbachev Factor (Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press, 1997), chap. 5.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  10. See A. Haroon Akram-Lodhi, “The Agrarian Question, Past and Present,” The Journal of Peasant Studies, vol. 25, no. 4 (July 1998), pp. 134–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Robert H. Bates, “Lessons from History, or the Perfidy of English Exceptionalism and the Significance of Historical France,” World Politics, vol. XL, no. 4 (July 1988), pp. 499–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. George C. Comninell, “English Feudalism and the Origins of Capitalism,” The Journal of Peasant Studies, vol. 27, no. 4 (July 2000), p. 3.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. See William C. Thiesenhusen, ed., Searching for Agrarian Reform in Latin America (Boston: Unwin Hyman, 1989);

    Google Scholar 

  14. Alain de Janvry, The Agrarian Question and Reformism in Latin America (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1981).

    Google Scholar 

  15. Common foci have been economic issues such as agricultural development, ensuring food supplies to urban populations, food price policies, food subsidy policies, food trade policies, peasant differentiation, or land distribution to peasant households. See Henry Bernstein, “Agrarian Questions Then and Now,” The Journal of Peasant Studies, vol. 24, nos. 1–2 (October 1996 and January 1997), pp. 22–59.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Michael Lipton, Why Poor People Stay Poor: Urban Bias in World Development (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press 1977).

    Google Scholar 

  17. James C. Scott, The Moral Economy of the Peasant: Rebellion and Subsistence in Southeast Asia (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1976).

    Google Scholar 

  18. Robert H. Bates, Markets and States in Tropical Africa: The Political Basis of Agricultural Policies (Berkeley: University of California Press 1981);

    Google Scholar 

  19. and Robert H. Bates, Essays on the Political Economy of Rural Africa (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1983).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  20. See David A. J. Macey, William Pyle, and Stephen K. Wegren, eds., Building Market Institutions in Post-Communist Agriculture: Land, Credit, and Assistance (Lanham, MD: Lexington Books, 2004).

    Google Scholar 

  21. Serguey Braguinsky and Grigory Yavlinsky, Incentives and Institutions: The Transition to a Market Economy in Russia (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000), chap. 6.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Anders Aslund, How Russia Became a Market Economy (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1995), p. 12.

    Google Scholar 

  23. See Marshall I. Goldman, The Piratization of Russia: Russian Reform Goes Awry (London and New York: Routledge, 2003), chap. 5.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  24. Peter Reddaway and Dmitri Glinski, The Tragedy of Russia’s Reforms: Market Bolshevism Against Democracy (Washington, DC: US Institute of Peace, 2001), chap. 5.

    Google Scholar 

  25. See e.g., Johan P. M. Swinnen, Allan Buckwell, and Erik Mathijs, eds., Agricultural Privatization, Land Reform, and Farm Restructuring in Central and Eastern Europe (Aldershot: Ashgate, 1997);

    Google Scholar 

  26. and Stephen K. Wegren, ed., Land Reform in the Former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe (New York and London: Routledge, 1998).

    Google Scholar 

  27. This point follows from Samuel L. Popkin, The Rational Peasant: The Political Economy of Rural Society in Vietnam (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1979).

    Google Scholar 

  28. Timothy J. Colton, “Economics and Voting in Russia,” Post-Soviet Affairs, vol. 12, no. 4 (October–December 1996), pp. 289–317.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Ralph S. Clem and Peter R. Craumer, “A Rayon-Level Analysis of the Russian Election and Constitutional Plebiscite of December 1993,” Post-Soviet Geography, vol. 36, no. 8 (October 1995), p. 84;

    Google Scholar 

  30. and Clem and Craumer, “The Geography of the Russian 1995 Parliamentary Election: Continuity, Change, and Correlates,” Post-Soviet Geography, vol. 36, no. 10 (December 1995), pp. 587–616.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Timothy J. Colton, “Determinants of the Party Vote,” in Timothy J. Colton and Jerry F. Hough, eds., Growing Pains: Russian Democracy and the Election of 1993 (Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution, 1998), pp. 75–114;

    Google Scholar 

  32. and Yitzhak M. Brudny, “Continuity or Change in Russian Electoral Patterns? The December 1999–March 2000 Election Cycle,” in Archie Brown, ed., Contemporary Russian Politics: A Reader (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001), pp. 154–78.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Marie Lavigne, The Economics of Transition: From Socialist Economy to Market Economy, 2nd ed. (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1999), chap. 4;

    Book  Google Scholar 

  34. and Leslie Holmes, Post-Communism (Durham: Duke University Press, 1997), chap. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  35. See Shwu-Eng H. Webb and Francis C. Tuan, “China’s Agricultural Reforms: Evaluation and Outlook,” in Joint Economic Committee, China’s Economic Dilemmas in the 1990s: The Problems of Reforms, Modernization, and Interdependence, Joint Committee Print, 102nd Congress, 1st session (Washington, DC: GPO, 1991), pp. 365–84;

    Google Scholar 

  36. and S. Lee Travers, “Getting Rich Through Diligence: Peasant Income after the Reforms,” in Elizabeth J. Perry and Christine Wong, eds., The Political Economy of Reform in Post-Mao China (Cambridge: Council on East Asian Studies/Harvard University Press, 1985), chap. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  37. Douglass C. North, “The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics to an Understanding of the Transition Problem,” (Helsinki: UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research, 1997), p. 16.

    Google Scholar 

  38. However, poliry innovation alone is not adequate. In a very insightful book, Neil Melvin argues that policy innovation was occurring in agriculture even during the Soviet period, in particular the post-Soviet period, but that institutional capacity to implement and fulfill policy was decaying over time. See Neil J. Melvin, Soviet Power and the Countryside: Policy Innovation and Institutional Decay (United Kingdom and New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2003).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  39. See Gabriel A. Almond, et al., Comparative Politics: A Theoretical Framework, 3rd ed. (New York: Longman, 2001), chap. 1;

    Google Scholar 

  40. and Charles E. Lindblom, The Policy-Making Process, 2nd ed. (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1980), chap. 10.

    Google Scholar 

  41. For more on which parties had agrarian planks in their party programs, see Renata Yanbukh, “Driving Forces in Russian Agrarian Policy in the 1990s,” in L. Alexander Norsworthy, ed., Russian Views of the Transition in the Rural Sector: Structures, Policy Outcomes, and Adaptive Responses (Washington, DC: The World Bank, 2000), p. 49.

    Google Scholar 

  42. V. V. Patsiorkovski, “Problemy sela,” in N. M. Rimashevskaia, ed., Rossiia—2000: sotsial’no demograficheskaia situatsiia (Moscow: Institute for Social-Economic Problems of the Population, 2001), p. 249.

    Google Scholar 

  43. For an analysis of regional differences based on survey data, see Stephen K. Wegren, David J. O’Brien, and Valeri V. Patsiorkovski, “Household Responses, Regional Diversity, and Contemporary Agrarian Reform in Russia,” The Journal of Peasant Studies, vol. 31, nos. 3–4 (April–July 2004), pp. 552–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Richard Rose, “Uses of Social Capital in Russia: Modern, Pre-Modern, and Anti-Modern,” Post-Soviet Affairs, vol. 16, no. 1 (January–March 2000), pp. 33–57.

    Google Scholar 

  45. David J. O’Brien, Valeri V. Patsiorkovski, and Larry D. Dershem, Household Capital and the Agrarian Problem in Russia (Aldershot: Ashgate, 2000), chap. 6.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Copyright information

© 2005 Stephen K. Wegren

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Wegren, S.K. (2005). Peasants’ Moral Economy and Implications for Russia’s Agrarian Capitalism. In: The Moral Economy Reconsidered. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230601130_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics