Skip to main content

The Theory of Imaginary Money from Charlemagne to the French Revolution

  • Chapter

Abstract

If one reads the books on monetary subjects that were written in the period from the sixteenth to the eighteenth century, one frequently encounters the concept of ‘imaginary money’. Other terms used are ‘ideal money’, ‘political money’, moneta numeraria, ‘money of account’. What these terms meant was not very clear even to contemporaries. The most authoritative writer among the historians of French monetary vicissitudes, François Le Blanc, resigned himself to defining as imaginary any kind of money which, ‘properly speaking, is but a collective term comprising a certain number of real moneys’. The imaginary money which almost everywhere was called ‘pound’ or an equivalent term such as ‘livre’, ‘lira’, ‘pond’, was, in Le Blanc’s words, ‘never changing in value; in fact, we have used it since the time of Charlemagne, and it has always been worth 20 sous (shillings), and each sou, 12 deniers (pence)’.1 It is called ‘imaginary’ because of the fact that it has never been coined; ‘because we have never had a real specie which has consistently been worth 20 sous or one worth 12 deniers’. Although from time immemorial men have neither seen nor touched any imaginary money, nevertheless, in the remote past it was something real, ‘since if we go back to the time when in France people began to count in pounds, shillings, and pence, we shall find that these imaginary moneys owe their origin to a real thing’.

A translation, by Giorgio Tagliacozzo, of ‘Teoria della moneta immaginaria nel tempo da Carlomagno alla rivoluzione francese’, Rivista di storia economica, 1936, I, 1–35. The essay is printed here with the permission of President Einaudi, who has approved the translation. The editors acknowledge the valuable assistance of Raymond de Roover in the preparation of the manuscript.

With the approval of the author, paragraphs 31, 32, 33 and 35 were omitted from the translation. Paragraph 34 of the original is number 32 in the present version; to preserve the continuity of the argument President Einaudi has made a brief addition to this paragraph. The notes of the original article have been included a few notes added by the translator.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. François Le Blanc, Traité historique des monnoyes de France (Paris, 1690), pp.xxi, xxv, and passim.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Dutot, Réflexions politiques sur les finances et le commerce (The Hague, 1754), Vol. II, pp.4–5.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Giovanni Antonio Fabbrini, Dell’indole e qualità naturali e civili della moneta (Rome, 1750), p.93.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Ferdinando Galiani, Della moneta (Naples, 1750), pp.99 and 101 (ed. by Nicolini, Bari, 1915, pp.87–8).

    Google Scholar 

  5. A. Messedaglia, La moneta e il sistema monetario in generale (Rome, 1882), ch. 7, p.1.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Luigi Valeriani, Ricerche critiche ed economiche … sulle monete di conto (Bologna, 1819), Pr. I, pp.150–1.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Not in all three denominations: pounds, shillings, and pence. According to Le Blanc (Traité, p.xxii), as we have seen, only silver shillings were coined; according to Adolphe Landry, Essai économique sur les mutations des monnaies dans l’ancienne France de Philippe le Bel à Charles VII (Paris, 1910), p.11, only the penny (denarius) was coined.

    Google Scholar 

  8. The present study was undertaken as a result of the recent publication of a hitherto unedited memoir by the Seigneur de Malestroit, author of the paradoxes made famous by the Réponse de Bodin. For the convenience of the reader, the text of the ‘Paradoxes’ and a second reply by Alexandre de la Tourette to the memoir of Malestroit are republished in the same volume; Paradoxes inédits du Seigneur de Malestroit touchant les monnoyes avec la réponse du Président de la Tourette, ed. by Luigi Einaudi (Turin: Giulio Einaudi, 1936).

    Google Scholar 

  9. Cesare Beccaria, ‘Del disordine e de’ rimedi delle monete nello stato di Milano nell’anno 1762’, in Le opere, Vol. I (Florence: Le Monnier, 1854), pp.470–1.

    Google Scholar 

  10. ‘Delia moneta e de suoi surrogati’, Introduction to Vol. VI of the Second Series of the Biblioteca dell’economista, 1857, pp.xxxv–liv; republished in F. Ferrara, Esame storicocritico di economisti, 1891, Vol. II, Pt I, pp.324–44.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Luca Einaudi Riccardo Faucci Roberto Marchionatti

Copyright information

© 2006 Ente Luigi Einaudi

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Einaudi, L., Faucci, R., Marchionatti, R. (2006). The Theory of Imaginary Money from Charlemagne to the French Revolution. In: Einaudi, L., Faucci, R., Marchionatti, R. (eds) Luigi Einaudi. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230522978_13

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics