Advertisement

Monetary Policy Implementation: A Microstructure Approach

  • Perry Mehrling
  • Neil T. Skaggs
Chapter

Abstract

In classic central banking theory, the ‘discount house’ played a central role (Bagehot, 1873, Sayers, 1976).1 As holders of short-term commercial bills, the discount houses financed the holding of goods on their way from producers to consumers, and, in turn, financed themselves primarily by borrowing from banks. Just so, an expansion of trade went hand in hand with an expansion of both the assets and liabilities of the discount houses, and also an expansion of both the assets and liabilities of the banking system. Looking through the balance sheet relationships, it was clear to observers that the expansion of trade was financed by an expansion of bank money, meaning the deposit liabilities of the banking system.

Keywords

Monetary Policy Central Bank Balance Sheet Federal Reserve Money Market 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Adrian, Tobias and Michael J. Fleming (2005). “What Financing Data Reveal about Dealer Leverage.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Current Issues in Economics and Finance 11:3.Google Scholar
  2. Bagehot, Walter (1873). Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market. London: Henry King.Google Scholar
  3. Bagehot, Walter (pseud.) (1971). “The Only Game in Town.” Financial Analysts Journal 27:2 (March/April), 12–14, 22. Reprinted as Treynor (1995).Google Scholar
  4. Biais, Bruno, Larry Glosten, and Chester Spatt (2005). “Market Microstructure: A Survey of Microfoundations, Empirical Results, and Policy Implications.” Journal of Financial Markets 8, 217–264.Google Scholar
  5. Bank for International Settlements (1999). “Implications of Repo Markets for Central Banks.” Report of Committee on the Global Financial System, No. 10.Google Scholar
  6. Bartolini, Leonardo, Spence Hilton, and Allesandro Prati (2005). “Money Market Integration.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Staff Report No. 227.Google Scholar
  7. Bartolini, Leonardo, Svenja Gudell, Spence Hilton, and Krista Schwarz (2005). “Intraday Trading in the Overnight Federal Funds Market.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Current Issues in Economics and Finance 11:11.Google Scholar
  8. Bernanke, Ben S. (2005). Implementing Monetary Policy. Washington, DC: Federal Reserve Board.Google Scholar
  9. Bindseil, Ulrich (2004). Monetary Policy Implementation: Theory, Past, and Present. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  10. Black, Fischer (1970). “Banking and Interest Rates in a World without Money: The Effects of Uncontrolled Banking.” Journal of Bank Research 1, 8–20.Google Scholar
  11. Bloomfield, Arthur I. (1959). Monetary Policy under the International Gold Standard: 1880–1914. New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.Google Scholar
  12. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (1971–1972). Reappraisal of the Federal Reserve Discount Mechanism, 3 vols. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.Google Scholar
  13. Bond Market Association (2005). “Repo and Securities Lending Survey of U.S. Markets.” Research (January).Google Scholar
  14. Carpenter, Seth and Selva Demiralp (2006). “The Liquidity Effect in the Federal Funds Market: Evidence from Daily Open Market Operations.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 38:4 (June), 901–920.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Cecchetti, Stephen (2005). Money, Banking, and Financial Markets. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
  16. Choudhry, Moorad (2002). The Repo Handbook. Boston: Butterworth-Heinemann.Google Scholar
  17. Clews, Roger (2005). “Implementing Monetary Policy: Reforms to the Bank of England’s Operations in the Money Market.” Bank of England, Quarterly Bulletin (Summer), 211–220.Google Scholar
  18. Demiralp, Selva, Brian Preslopsky, and William Whitesell (2004). “Overnight Interbank Loan Markets.” Unpublished mimeo. Washington, DC: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.Google Scholar
  19. Evans, Martin (2005). “Foreign Exchange Market Microstructure.” Mimeo, Georgetown University, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
  20. Federal Reserve Bank of New York (2006). Domestic Open Market Operations during 2005. New York: FRBNY.Google Scholar
  21. Friedman, Benjamin M. (2000). “Decoupling at the Margin: The Threat to Monetary Policy from the Electronic Revolution in Banking.” NBER Working Paper No. 7955. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
  22. Furfine, Craig H. (1999). “The Microstructure of the Federal Funds Market.” Financial Markets, Institutions and Instruments 8:5 (November), 24–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Furfine, Craig H. (2000). “Interbank Payments and the Daily Federal Funds Rate.” Journal of Monetary Economics 46, 535–553.Google Scholar
  24. Garbade, Kenneth D. (2006). “The Evolution of Repo Contracting Conventions.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Economic Policy Review 12:1 (May), 27–42.Google Scholar
  25. Hamilton, James D. (1996). “The Daily Market for Federal Funds.” Journal of Political Economy 104:1 (February), 26–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Hamilton, James D. (1997). “Measuring the Liquidity Effect.” American Economic Review 87:1 (March), 80–97.Google Scholar
  27. Harris, Larry (2003). Trading and Exchanges: Market Microstructure for Practitioners. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  28. Henckel, Timo, Alain Ize, and Arto Kovanen (1999). “Central Banking without Central Bank Money.” Working Paper WP/99/92 of the International Monetary Fund. Washington, DC: IMF.Google Scholar
  29. Hilton, Spence (2005). “Trends in Federal Funds Rate Volatility.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Current Issues in Economics and Finance 11:7.Google Scholar
  30. International Capital Market Association (2006). European Repo Market Survey No. 10. Zurich: ICMA.Google Scholar
  31. Lyons, Richard K. (2001). The Microstructure Approach to Exchange Rates. Cambridge, MA: MIT University Press.Google Scholar
  32. Maginn, John L. and Donald L. Tuttle (1983). Managing Investment Portfolios: A Dynamic Process. Sponsored by the Institute of Chartered Financial Analysts. Boston: Warren, Gorham and Lamont.Google Scholar
  33. McAndrews, James (2005). “The Microstructure of Money.” Unpublished mimeo. Federal Reserve Bank of New York.Google Scholar
  34. Mehrling, Perry (1997). The Money Interest and the Public Interest, American Monetary Thought 1920–1970. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  35. Minsky, Hyman P. (1957). “Central Banking and Money Market Changes.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 71:2 (May), 171–187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Mishkin, Frederic S. (2004). The Economics of Money, Banking, and Financial Markets, 7th ed. Boston: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
  37. Modigliani, Franco, Robert Rasche, and J. Phillip Cooper (1970). “Central Bank Policy, the Money Supply, and the Short Term Rate of Interest.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 2:2 (May), 166–218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. O’Hara, Maureen (1995). Market Microstructure Theory. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers.Google Scholar
  39. Sayers, Richard S. (1936). Bank of England Operations, 1890–1914. London: P.S. King and Son.Google Scholar
  40. Sayers, Richard S. (1957). Central Banking after Bagehot. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  41. Sayers, Richard S. (1960). Modern Banking, 5th ed. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  42. Sayers, Richard S. (1976). The Bank of England 1891–1944, 3 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  43. Stigum, Marcia (1990). The Money Market, 3rd ed. Burr Ridge, IL: Irwin Professional Publishing.Google Scholar
  44. Taylor, Ellen. (1995). Trader’s Guide to the Repo Market. Greenwich, CT: Asset International.Google Scholar
  45. Taylor, John B. (2001). “Expectations, Open Market Operations, and Changes in the Federal Funds Rate.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 83:4, 33–47.Google Scholar
  46. Tobin, James (1969). “A General Equilibrium Approach to Monetary Theory.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 1:1 (February), 15–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Treynor, Jack (1987). “The Economics of the Dealer function.” Financial Analysts Journal 43:6 (November-December), 27–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  48. Treynor, Jack (1995). “The Only Game in Town.” Financial Analysts Journal 51:1 (January/February), 81–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Whitesell, William (2003). “Tunnels and Reserves in Monetary Policy Implementation.” Working Paper. Washington, DC: Board of Governors.Google Scholar
  50. Woodford, Michael (2001). “Monetary Policy in the Information Economy.” Unpublished mimeo, Princeton University.Google Scholar

References

  1. Fullarton, John (1969 [1845]). On the Regulation of Currencies. New York: A.M. Kelley.Google Scholar
  2. Thornton, Henry (1978 ]1802]). An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of Great Britain. Edited by F.A. Hayek. Fairfield, NJ: A.M. Kelley.Google Scholar
  3. Woodford, Michael (2003). Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© Perry Mehrling and Neil T. Skaggs 2010

Authors and Affiliations

  • Perry Mehrling
  • Neil T. Skaggs

There are no affiliations available

Personalised recommendations