Advertisement

Sharefarming before 1500: A Hidden Practice

  • Elizabeth Griffiths
  • Mark Overton
Chapter

Abstract

Where to begin a history of sharefarming in England? If the definition of sharefarming is confined to the classic versions, involving the sharing of the input and output, the task is beset with difficulty. Medieval documents, which provide such a precise record of the transfer and ownership of land, are more or less silent on farming to halves, as it did not involve a transfer of ownership or obligations.1 Manorial court rolls, surveys, estate rentals and accounts that were designed to inform the lord of the rents and services owing to him from his tenants, say little about their farming and do not necessarily reflect the actual occupancy of a holding or how it was used. However, formal leases often contained restrictions against subletting, and it is in this context, when infringements were punished in the manor courts, that evidence of farming to halves comes to light.2 These formal leases included stock and land leases which were of great antiquity.3 Lennard dates them back to the Anglo-Saxon period, whilst Venn describes métayage as the most ancient tenure of all, and in its original conception exactly akin to the English stock and land tenure.4 Broderick, in his nineteenth-century critique of the landlord-tenant system, compares the stock and land lease to the métairies of south west Europe and recommends its revival in England.5 Thus, if we extend our definition of sharefarming to include the stock and land lease, generally considered by historians and economists to be the English version of métayage, we can see that forms of sharefarming date from the earliest times and most likely predated fixed money rent.6

Keywords

Medieval Period Teenth Century Land Lease Large Tenant Peasant Family 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. 2.
    R.H. Hilton, ‘Why was there so little champart rent in Medieval England?’, Journal of Peasant Studies, 17 (1990) 509–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. 4.
    R.V. Lennard, Rural England 1086–1135: A Study of Social and Agrarian Conditions, (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1959), p. 194Google Scholar
  3. J.A. Venn, The Foundations of Agricultural Economics, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1923), pp. 43–7.Google Scholar
  4. 6.
    M.M. Postan, Essays on Medieval Agriculture and General Problems of the Medieval Economy, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973), pp. 134–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. 8.
    B.M.S. Campbell, ‘The Agrarian Problem in the Early Fourteenth Century’, Past & Present, 188 (2005), p. 10.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. 20.
    R.H. Hilton, The English Peasantry in the Later Middle Ages, (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1973), p. 43.Google Scholar
  7. 28.
    F.L. Galassi, ‘Moral Hazard and Asset Specificity in the Renaissance: The Economics of Sharecropping in 1427 Florence’, in K.D. Kauffman (ed.) Advances in Agricultural Economic History, Vol. 1, New Frontiers in Agricultural History, (Stamford, CT: JAI Press, 2000), pp. 177–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. 32.
    J.A. Raftis, Tenure and Mobility: Studies in the Social History of the Mediaeval English Village, (Toronto: Pontifical Institute of Mediaeval Studies, 1964), pp. 44Google Scholar
  9. J. Hatcher, Rural Economy and Society in the Duchy of Cornwall, 1300–1500, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1970)Google Scholar
  10. 39.
    A.V. Chayanov, The Theory of Peasant Farming, ed. D. Thorner, B. Kerbaly and R.E.F. Smith, (Homewood, III.: American Economic Association, 1966), pp. 53–69.Google Scholar
  11. 40.
    R.M. Smith (ed.) Land, Kinship and Life-Cycle, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984).Google Scholar
  12. 42.
    S. Ogilvie, ‘“Whatever is, is right”? Economic institutions in pre-industrial Europe’, Economic History Review, 2nd series, 60 (2007) 649–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. 46.
    Z. Razi, ‘Family, Land and the Village Community in Later Medieval England’, Past & Present, 93 (1981) p. 10.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. 52.
    B. Harvey, ‘The leasing of the Abbot of Westminster’s Demesne in the later middle ages’, Economic History Review, 2nd series, 22 (1969) 17–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. 56.
    R.H. Britnell, Britain and Ireland, 1050–1530: Economy and Society, (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2004), pp. 401–4.Google Scholar
  16. 57.
    R.H. Britnell, ‘The Pastons and their Norfolk’, Agricultural History Review, 36 (1988) 132–44Google Scholar
  17. C. Richmond, ‘Landlord and Tenant: the Paston Evidence’, in J. Kermode (ed.) Enterprise and Individuals in Fifteenth Century England, (Stroud: Alan Sutton, 1996), pp. 25–42Google Scholar
  18. 60.
    B.M.S. Campbell, ‘Agricultural Progress in Medieval England: Some Evidence from Eastern Norfolk’, Economic History Review, 2nd series, 36 (1983) 26–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. R.H. Britnell, ‘The occupation of the land: Eastern England’, in E. Miller (ed.) The Agrarian History of England and Wales, Vol. III, 1348–1500, (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), pp. 53–66Google Scholar
  20. 65.
    R.W. Hoyle, ‘Agrarian agitation in mid-sixteenth-century Norfolk: A petition of 1553’, Historical Journal, 44 (2001), p. 237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. 68.
    R.A. Dodgshon, Land and Society in Early Scotland, (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1981), pp. 245–53.Google Scholar
  22. 75.
    R.A. Dodgshon, ‘Coping with Risk: Subsistence Crises in the Scottish Highlands and Islands, 1600–1800’, Rural History, 15 (2004) 1–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Elizabeth Madeleine Griffiths and Mark Overton 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  • Elizabeth Griffiths
    • 1
  • Mark Overton
    • 1
  1. 1.University of ExeterUK

Personalised recommendations