Skip to main content

Introduction

  • Chapter
Regional Integration
  • 150 Accesses

Abstract

In 1828, an economic negotiator for the German state Hesse-Darmstadt, which was in the midst of a severe recession, met with Prussia’s finance minister to propose a trade treaty. Having been rebuffed two years earlier, he had low expectations for a close relationship with the wealthy Prussia. To his surprise, the finance minister embraced not just a preferential trade treaty but a customs union, a much deeper form of economic integration. There was a catch: as a first step to integration, Prussia alone would set the tariff levels the two states would charge importers. In exchange for a share of the collected tariffs that significantly exceeded what it could have earned on its own, Hesse-Darmstadt readily agreed to this stipulation. Recognizing that the smaller state’s leader faced challenges from political forces at home that favored liberal institutions over monarchies, and wanting to attract an even more important member state, Hesse-Kassel, Prussia agreed that subsequent tariff decisions would be made under rules that gave member states an equal voice in policy making. These same two rules applied to states that subsequently joined the customs union, which eventually became the 1834 Zollverein (literally, toll union). By 1871, when the German Empire was created after the Franco-Prussian War, nearly every German state had joined the Zollverein.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. On the logic of political survival, see Bruce Bueno de Mesquita et al., The Logic of Political Survival (Cambridge, MA, and London: The MIT Press, 2003).

    Google Scholar 

  2. Terry M. Moe, “The New Economics of Organization,” American Journal of Political Science 28 (1984): 756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. For recent developments in delegation theory applied to international relations, particularly international organzations, see Michael J. Tierney, “Delegation Success and Policy Failure: Collective Delegation and the Search for Iraqi Weapons of Mass Destruction,” Law and Contemporary Problems 71, no. 1 (2008): 283–312;

    Google Scholar 

  4. Curtis A. Bradley and Judith G. Kelley, “The Concept of International Delegation,” Law and Contemporary Problems 71, no. 1 (2008): 1–36;

    Google Scholar 

  5. Darren G. Hawkins et al., eds., Delegation and Agency in International Organizations (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2006);

    Google Scholar 

  6. Mark A. Pollack, The Engines of European Integration: Delegation, Agency, and Agenda Setting in the EU (Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press, 2003);

    Book  Google Scholar 

  7. and Daniel L. Nielson and Michael J. Tierney, “Delegation to International Organizations: Agency Theory and World Bank Environmental Reform,” International Organization 57, no. 2 (2003): 241–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. The EU literature is vast and has been covered in detail elsewhere. For excellent reviews of the literature, see Andrew Moravcsik, The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1998);

    Google Scholar 

  9. Walter Mattli, The Logic of Regional Integration: Europe and Beyond (Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999); Mark A. Pollack, “International Relations Theory and European Integration,” Journal of Common Market Studies 39, no. 2(2001); and “Theorizing the European Union: International Organization, Domestic Polity, or Experiment in New Governance?” Annual Review of Political Science 8(2005). For explanation of why some institutions are intergovernmental and others supranational,

    Book  Google Scholar 

  10. see Wayne Sandholtz and Alec Stone Sweet, eds., European Integration and Supranational Governance (Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press, 1998);

    Google Scholar 

  11. Alec Stone Sweet, Wayne Sandholtz, and Neil Fligstein, eds., The Institutionalization of Europe (Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press, 2001); Pollack, Engines of European Integration.

    Google Scholar 

  12. David A. Lake, Entangling Relations: American Foreign Policy in Its Century, Princeton Studies in International History and Politics (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  13. Alexander J. Motyl, Imperial Ends: The Decay, Collapse, and Revival of Empires (New York: Columbia University Press, 2001).

    Google Scholar 

  14. Stephen D. Krasner, “Approaches to the State: Alternative Conceptions and Historical Dynamics,” Comparative Politics 16 (1984). Krasner borrowed the term from evolutionary theory;

    Google Scholar 

  15. see Niles Eldridge and Stephen Jay Gould, “Punctuated Equilibria: An Alternative to Phyletic Gradualism,” in Models in Paleontology, ed. Tom Schopf (San Francisco: Freeman Cooper, 1972).

    Google Scholar 

  16. Alexander L. George and Andrew Bennett, Case Studies and Theory Development in the Social Sciences (Cambridge: MIT, 2005).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Copyright information

© 2009 Kathleen J. Hancock

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hancock, K.J. (2009). Introduction. In: Regional Integration. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230101913_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics