Skip to main content

Double Shift, Double Balance: Housework in the Presence of Children in the United States

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Abstract

This chapter focuses on the extent to which women combine housework with simultaneously minding children. Given that housework can be done along with child caregiving, but presumably at a cost, this characteristic of home production time constitutes another margin in women’s lives where the balancing act of their many roles plays out. After exploring the existing literature and a simple conceptual model, the authors analyze data from the American Time Use Surveys, 2003–2011. The results indicate systematic differences in doing housework alone or with or without children present according to a number of characteristics of women and their households. Women with more minutes in employment that day are more likely to engage in household chores alone and are less likely to have children present while doing housework.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    We use the terms “home production” and “housework” interchangeably to refer to doing household chores; it does not refer to child care. The term non-market work encompasses both home production and the care of children.

  2. 2.

    See Connelly and Kimmel (2013) for a detailed summary of the literature on these trends in the United States.

  3. 3.

    An exception is Foster and Kalenkoski (2015) who, using experimental data, examine the effects of multi-tasking on productivity in the context of doing either a household chore or childcare activity only, versus engaging in both activities simultaneously.

  4. 4.

    We do not attempt to establish empirical evidence to support this assumption, however, see Foster and Kalenkoski (2015) for experimental evidence on the negative effect of children’s presence on efficiency in home production.

  5. 5.

    It is widely recognized that the response rate for the ATUS, while higher than for most time use diary surveys, is lower than ideal (approximately 54–58%). Abraham et al. (2006) analyze the pattern of non-response and conclude that it is largely due to failure to contact respondents (as opposed to refusal) which appears to be relatively randomly distributed across the pool of possible respondents. Therefore, meaningful bias due to sample selection is unlikely to be present.

  6. 6.

    The detailed listing of time use designations of the ATUS can be found at the Bureau of Labor Statistics website (www.bls.gov/tus/lexicons.htm).

  7. 7.

    As argued by Folbre et al. (2005) and Folbre and Yoon (2007), the data may underestimate the extent of child care as a secondary activity if, for example, young children who are asleep or playing in another room are not considered to be in the presence of the respondent.

  8. 8.

    We use Stata for all estimations.

  9. 9.

    Because of the complexities of differing functional forms in Eq. (2), we do not allow for the possibility of correlated error terms across time use categories as in, for example, Kalenkoski et al. (2005) and Kimmel and Connelly (2007). If such correlation is present, which is reasonable to assume, not accounting for it reduces the statistical efficiency of Eq. (2), resulting in larger standard errors for the estimated coefficients. However, the estimates maintain the property of unbiasedness. Given that our primary purpose in estimating (2) is to derive unbiased instruments to use in the estimation of (1) rather than to test hypotheses within (2), the loss of efficiency is not a cause for concern.

  10. 10.

    Breusch-Pagan tests indicated the presence of heteroscedasticity in Eqs. (1) and (2), thus, we estimate using the robust option to adjust estimated standard errors.

  11. 11.

    Wages are estimated using the Heckman sample selection model. The wage equation includes the following variables that are not included in Eq. (2): age-squared and education-squared, the state unemployment rate, the unemployment rate interacted with the pre-2008 dummy, and an indicator of whether the state minimum wage is higher than the federally mandated minimum wage.

  12. 12.

    As is common in this literature, we treat women’s marital status as exogenous. See Blau and Kahn (2007) for one study that controls statistically for the possible endogeneity of marriage in a model of women’s labor supply and finds that results are generally not sensitive to selection into marriage.

  13. 13.

    Full results for the sub-samples are available upon request.

  14. 14.

    Approximately 10% of observations are missing information on income and, therefore, are dropped. An alternative to dropping these observations would be to use spouse’s earnings to proxy for exogenous income. Because we include unmarried women in the sample, this measure seems more problematic due to the systematic nature of the missing information, and the much larger portion of the sample affected. Nonetheless, we check for sensitivity to this alternative specification. Also, the time gap between household income data (from the CPS), and the data used to calculate women’s labor market earnings (from the ATUS collected several months later), results in the latter being larger than the former for a small percentage of observations. We therefore also estimate two versions of the model, one setting negative values to zero and one treating them as missing. Results are not sensitive to these alternatives; reported results set negative values to zero.

  15. 15.

    The F values for joint significance in the non-market work and leisure equations are 16.39 and 13.35, respectively, and the corresponding chi-squared value for the employment equation is 69.24.

  16. 16.

    We also estimated Eq. (1) using a more limited sample, based on women with children younger than age 13. The results are generally highly consistent across samples, especially with respect to the explanatory variables of greatest interest to us.

  17. 17.

    Simulations are conducted for prototypes based on marital status and education level, and using the modal or mean value within each prototype group for other explanatory variables. Detailed simulation results are available upon request.

References

  • Abraham, Katherine G., Aaron Maitland, and Suzanne M. Bianchi (2006). Nonresponse in the American Time Use Survey: Who Is Missing from the Data and How Much Does It Matter? Public Opinion Quarterly, 70(5), 676–703.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aguiar, Mark, and Erik Hurst (2007). Measuring Trends in Leisure: The Allocation of Time over Five Decades. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3), 969–1006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aguiar, Mark, and Erik Hurst (2009). A summary of trends in American time allocation: 1965-2005. Social Indicators Research, 93, 57–64.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aguiar, Mark, Erik Hurst, and Loukas Karabarbounis (2013). Time Use During the Great Recession. American Economic Review, 103(5), 1664–1696.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belkin, Lisa (2003). The Opt-out Revolution. New York Times Magazine (October 26).

    Google Scholar 

  • Belkin, Lisa (2013). The Retro Wife Opts Out: What Has Changed and What Still Needs To. The Huffington Post (March 19).

    Google Scholar 

  • Berik, Günseli, and Ebru Kongar (2013). Time Allocation of Married Mothers and Fathers in Hard Times: The 2007–2009 US Recession. Feminist Economics, 19(3), 208–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi, Suzanne (2000). Maternal Employment and Time with Children: Dramatic Change or Surprising Continuity? Demography, 37(4), 401–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bittman, Michael, and Judy Wajcman (2000). The Rush Hour: The Character of Leisure Time and Gender Equity. Social Forces, 79(1), 165–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau, Francine D., and Lawrence M. Kahn (2007). Changes in the Labor Supply Behavior of Married Women: 1980–2000. Journal of Labor Economics, 25(3), 393–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bound, John, David A. Jaegar, and Regina M. Baker (1995). Problems with Instrumental Variables Estimation When the Correlation between the Instruments and the Endogeneous Explanatory Variable is Weak. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 90(430), 443–450.

    Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, Rachel, and Jean Kimmel (2009). Spousal Influences on Parents’ Non-market Time Choices. Review of Economics of the Household, 7, 361–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, Rachel, and Jean Kimmel (2010). The Time Use of Mothers in the United States at the Beginning of the 21st Century. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, Rachel, and Jean Kimmel (2013). Gender Differences in Unpaid Time Use by Family Structure. In Esther Redmount (ed.), Family Economics: How Households Impact Markets and Economic Growth. Santa Barbara, CA: ABC-CLIO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, Rachel, and Jean Kimmel (2015). If You’re Happy and You Know It: How Do Mothers and Fathers in the U.S. Really Feel about Caring for Their Children? Feminist Economics, 21(1), 1–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Floro, Maria Sagrario, and Marjorie Miles (2003). Time Use, Work and Overlapping Activities: Evidence from Australia. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 27, 881–904.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Folbre, Nancy, and Jayoung Yoon (2007). What Is Child Care? Lessons from Time-use Surveys of Major English-speaking Countries. Review of Economics of the Household, 5, 223–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Folbre, Nancy, Jayoung Yoon, Kade Finnoff, and Allison Sidle Fuligni (2005). By What Measure? Family Time Devoted to Children in the United States. Demography, 42(2), 373–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster, Gigi, and Charlene Kalenkoski (2015). Measuring the Relative Productivity of Multitasking to Sole-Tasking in Household Production: Experimental Evidence. Applied Economics, 47(16–18), 1847–1862.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, Liana, Wen-Jui Han, Christopher Rulm, and Jane Waldfogel (2013). Time for Children: Trends in the Employment Patterns of Parents, 1967-2009. Demography, 50(1), 25–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallberg, Daniel, and Anders Klevmarken (2003). Time for Children: A Study of Parent’s Time Allocation. Journal of Population Economics, 16, 205–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh, Daniel S., and Jungmin Lee (2007). Stressed Out on Four Continents: Time Crunch or Yuppie Kvetch? The Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(2), 374–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hill, Russell C., and Frank P. Stafford (1985). Parental Care of Children: Time Diary Estimates Of Quantity, Predictability, and Variety. In F. Thomas Juster and Frank P. Stafford (eds.), Time, Goods, and Well-Being (pp. 415–437). Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hochschild, Arlie Russell (1989). The Second Shift: Working Parents and the Revolution at Home. New York: Viking Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalenkoski, Charlene M., David C. Ribar, and Leslie S. Stratton (2005). Parental Child Care in Single-parent, Cohabiting and Married-couple Families: Time Diary Evidence from the United Kingdom. AEA Papers and Proceedings, 95(2), 194–198.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalenkoski, Charlene M., David C. Ribar, and Leslie S. Stratton (2009). The Influence of Wages on Parents’ Allocation of Time to Child Care and Market Work in the United Kingdom. Journal of Population Economics, 22, 399–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keith, Bryant, W., and Cathleen D. Zick (1996). An Examination of Parent-Child Shared Time. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 58(1), 227–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimmel, Jean, and Rachel Connelly (2007). Mothers’ Time Choices: Caregiving, Leisure, Home Production, and Paid Work. The Journal of Human Resources, 42(3), 643–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, Alan (2007). Are We Having More Fun Yet? Categorizing and Evaluating Changes in Time Allocation. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 193–215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milkie, Melissa A., Sara B. Raley, and Suzanne M. Bianchi (2009). Taking on the Second Shift: Time Allocations and Time Pressures of U.S. Parents with Preschoolers. Social Forces, 88(2), 487–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moro-Egido, Ana I. (2012). Changing Trends of Mothers’ Active and Passive Childcare Times. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 33, 11–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2014) Better Life Index. http://www.oecdbetterlifeindex.org/ (accessed August 2014).

  • Pew Research Center (2006). Who’s Feeling Rushed? (Hint: Ask a Working Mom). Social Trends Report (February 28).

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramey, Valerie, and Neville Francis (2009). A Century of Work and Leisure. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(2), 189–224.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruppanner, Leah, and Joy E. Pixley (2012). Work-to-Family and Family-to-Work Spillover: The Implications of Childcare Policy and Maximum Work-Hour Legislation. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 33, 283–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandberg, Sheryl (2013). Lean In: Women, Work and the Will to Lead. New York NY: Knopf Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sayer, Liana C. (2005). Gender, Time and Inequality: Trends in Women’s and Men’s Paid Work, Unpaid Work and Free Time. Social Forces, 84(1), 285–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sayer, Liana C., and Leigh Fine (2011). Racial-Ethnic Differences in U.S. Married Women’s and Men’s Housework. Social Indicators Research, 101, 259–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sayer, Liana C., Suzanne M. Bianchi, and John P. Robinson (2004). Are Parents Investing Less in Children? Trends in Mothers’ and Fathers’ Time with Children. American Journal of Sociology, 110(1), 1–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sayer, Liana C., Paula England, Michael Bittman, and Suzanne M. Bianchi (2009). How Long Is the Second (Plus First) Shift? Gender Differences in Paid, Unpaid and Total Work Time in Australia and the United States. Journal of Comparative Family Studies, 40(4), 523–545.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sevilla, Almudena, Jose I. Gimenez-Nadal, and Jonathan Gershuny (2012). Leisure Inequality in the United States: 1965–2003. Demography, 49(3), 939–964.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, Betsy, and Justin Wolfers (2009). The Paradox of Declining Female Happiness. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1(2), 190–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock, James H., and Motohiro Yogo (2005). Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression. In D.W.K. Andrews (ed.), Identification and Inference for Econometric Models (pp. 80–108). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, Juster, F., Paul N. Courant, and Greg K. Dow (1985). A Conceptual Framework for the Analysis of Time Allocation Data. In F. Thomas Juster and Frank P. Stafford (eds.), Time, Goods, and Well-Being (pp. 113–131). Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Wendy (2013). Parents’ Time with Kids More Rewarding than Paid Work – And More Exhausting. Pew Research Center (October).

    Google Scholar 

  • White House (2014) Summit on Working Families, http://workingfamiliessummit.org/ (accessed July 2014).

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Deborah S. DeGraff .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

Table A.1 Descriptive statistics for explanatory variables used in primary models
Table A.2 Summary of regression results for minutes in employment, non-market work, and leisure
Table A.3 Regression results for proportion of home production time spent alone
Table A.4 Regression results for proportion of home production time with children present

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

DeGraff, D.S., Centanni, R.M. (2017). Double Shift, Double Balance: Housework in the Presence of Children in the United States. In: Connelly, R., Kongar, E. (eds) Gender and Time Use in a Global Context. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-56837-3_13

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-56837-3_13

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, New York

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-137-56836-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-137-56837-3

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics