Skip to main content

Climbing Mount Everest: Paul Samuelson on Financial Theory and Practice

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Paul Samuelson

Part of the book series: Remaking Economics: Eminent Post-War Economists ((EPWE))

Abstract

Paul Samuelson regarded finance as the “Mount Everest” of economic pursuits. He proved that informationally efficient markets implied random price behavior and believed that very few investors could “beat the market.” Motivated by his study of the dismal performance of “managed money,” Samuelson was the first to advocate the creation of a low-cost stock index fund and his writings spurred Jack Bogle to create the S&P 500 Index Trust. His work on option theory brought him to the verge of the Black–Scholes formula, but the final equation eluded him. Samuelson warned investors that the Law of Large Numbers did not imply that investors with longer horizons should put a greater proportion of their portfolio in stocks but demonstrated that mean reversion of equity prices coupled with sufficient risk aversion would imply that strategy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 165.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Although Samuelson was not the economist with the greatest political impact, in my opinion, that honor goes for John Maynard Keynes in the first two-thirds of the twentieth century, and Milton Friedman in the last third.

  2. 2.

    See also an earlier review by Merton (1983).

  3. 3.

    This was evident by Merton’s 1969 class paper, “An Empirical Investigation of the Samuelson Rational Warrant Pricing Theory,” which became part of his MIT Ph.D. dissertation in 1970.

  4. 4.

    This article, published while a student at Harvard, was the second of nearly 1000 scholarly pieces that Samuelson published in his lifetime. The David M. Rubenstein Rare Book & Manuscript Library at Duke University contains almost 89,000 items (printed and teaching materials, correspondence, speeches and interviews, and other audiovisual materials) related to the work of Paul Samuelson, which they claim occupy 119 linear feet of shelf space!

  5. 5.

    It is well known that Friedman opposed approving Harry Markowitz’s Ph.D. dissertation, which was the foundation of modern portfolio theory and later worthy of a Nobel Prize in economics. Friedman regarded it as a statistical exercise, not an economic contribution. In contrast, Samuelson praised Markowitz in a 2010 article entitled, “On the Himalayan Shoulders of Harry Markowitz.” Friedman’s resistance to analyzing stock prices possibly arose from his work on the monetary history of the United States , which debunked the popular explanation that the stock market crash of 1929, not the collapse of the banking system, caused the Great Depression.

  6. 6.

    He understates his disappointment in his personal reminisces on modern finance theory (Samuelson 2009: 19) where he contends that his attempts to establish pricing theory for options fell “a bit short of the Black-Scholes-Merton Holy Grail.”

  7. 7.

    Vanguard’s index funds had an enormous impact on college pension practices as faculty agitated for inclusion of these funds to supplement TIAA-CREF, which had held a virtual monopoly.

  8. 8.

    See S&P Dow Jones Indices (2016). According to Thomson Reuters, ICI (topdowncharts.com), since the 2009 financial crisis about $750 billion of funds have moved out of actively managed accounts and over $1 trillion have moved into passive (indexed) accounts.

  9. 9.

    Milton Friedman also railed against those ceilings in a Newsweek article entitled “The Bank Depositor,” 7 November 1966.

  10. 10.

    Samuelson’s stake is worth about $750,000 in 2018 dollars. He was very comfortable financially, having earned millions from his bestselling textbook, Economics (Samuelson 1948). This text, through its 19 editions, has sold nearly 4 million copies and has been translated into 40 languages.

  11. 11.

    Weymar told Mallaby (2010: 64), “I thought random walk was bullshit. The whole idea that an individual can’t make serious money with a competitive edge over the rest of the market is wacko.”

  12. 12.

    In other words, Samuelson considered his “comparative advantage” was tackling tough economic problems, not trading strategies.

  13. 13.

    He also claimed that commodity trader Amos Hostetter Sr. (whose picture was on the wall of the Commodities Corporation) garnered positive returns over virtually every year in the half century before his death, a performance which would have virtually zero chance of being the result of random outcomes. See Samuelson (1989a: 7).

  14. 14.

    Samuelson cites Buffett’s: “Aw shucks, just buy a good business franchise at a favorable price!” See Samuelson (1993: 3).

  15. 15.

    Indeed, over the past 10 years, Berkshire Hathaway has underperformed the S&P 500.

  16. 16.

    The real return on short-term fixed income assets has fallen dramatically in recent years and has been less than zero over the past decade.

  17. 17.

    Today a large part of earnings is deployed for stock buybacks , also generating “systematic capital gains.”

  18. 18.

    The “Fed Model” received its name from a graph in the 22 July 1997 Fed Monetary Policy (“Humphrey-Hawkins”) Report to Congress. It was popularized by Edward Yardeni, then at Deutsche Morgan Grenfell.

  19. 19.

    He finally identified his colleague 28 years later in Samuelson (1989b: 292) as E. Cary Brown (one of my professors at MIT), referring to him as his “long-time boss.” Brown was chairman of the Economics Department for 18 years.

  20. 20.

    Zvi Bodie, who crusaded with Samuelson against the belief that in the long run stocks would always beat bonds, often mentioned my book, Stocks for the Long Run, as providing the basis for this incorrect belief (Bodie 1995). When I confronted Zvi and said that I never claimed that in my book, he agreed and replied, “I know you don’t, Jeremy, but everyone thinks you do!”

  21. 21.

    Research was initially undertaken as a project with Marshall Blume supported by the New York Stock Exchange in anticipation of its 200-year anniversary in 1987 (see Siegel 1992, 1994).

  22. 22.

    I retold this story at Samuelson’s 90th birthday celebration. It received loud chuckles from the audience and even Samuelson smiled.

  23. 23.

    For example, if we assume a long-run real rate on bonds of 2%, and an equity premium of 2% (which is still much larger than Mehra and Prescott propose), we get a real return on stocks of 4%, which corresponds to a 25 price-to-earnings ratio. These are all geometric returns.

  24. 24.

    Fortunately, a quarter of a century after receiving this letter I am basking in the “blessed territory.” From the date of this exchange through 31 July 2018, the US stock market has returned over 9.4% per year (about 7.1% after inflation is taken into account), more than its historical average. In contrast, a 25-year US government bond would have returned about 6%, and rolling over in bills, less than 2.5%. However, the ride to these great stock returns was rocky. I clearly would have been in the “cursed territory” at the bottom of the bear market in March 2009.

  25. 25.

    In January 1997, one month after Alan Greenspan, Chairman of the Federal Reserve, made his famous “Irrational Exuberance” speech, Samuelson wrote a short piece, “Dogma of the Decade: Sure-Thing Risk Erosion for Long-Horizon Investors” (Samuelson 1997) claiming that the “can’t-lose-in-equity” philosophy was flawed.

  26. 26.

    These returns can be simulated by a “bootstrapping” technique.

  27. 27.

    I was not the first to suggest that stock returns followed a mean-reverting process. Poterba and Summers (1988) and Fama and French (1988) showed that long-term stock returns did not conform to the random walk hypothesis. Mean reversion became even more apparent when I extended the stock return series back to 1802.

  28. 28.

    Analytically, if U(c) = c1−γ/(1 − γ), the class of investors who would hold more stocks are those with a risk coefficient γ > 1, i.e., those more risk averse than U(c) = log(c).

  29. 29.

    In Samuelson (1989a: 10; italics in original), he states that “the bulk of the empirical evidence, cross-sectional and from time series, is that real life investors are more risk-averse than Bernoulli utility function log(c).”

  30. 30.

    In their 2018 yearbook, Dimson et al.’s sixteen country sample was expanded to 21, and stock returns still dominated in all countries. Equities outperformed bonds by 4.3 percentage points per year and bonds by 3.2 percentage points. They state that “this provides a reassuring reminder that, over the long run, there has been a reward for the higher short-term risk from stocks” (Dimson et al. 2018: 24).

  31. 31.

    The importance of labor supply flexibility is found in Bodie et al. (1992).

References

  • Black, F. and M. Scholes (1973) “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,” Journal of Political Economy, 81: 637–654.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodie, Z. (1995) “On the Risks of Stocks in the Long Run,” Financial Analysts Journal, 51: 18–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodie Z., R.C. Merton and W. Samuelson (1992) “Labor Supply Flexibility and Portfolio Choice in a Life Cycle Model,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 16: 427–449.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bogle, J.C. (2005) “The Professor, the Student, and the Index Fund,” comments delivered at the Boston Security Analysts Society, 15 November. Available at http://johncbogle.com/wordpress/wp-content/uploads/2011/09/The-Professor-The-Student-and-the-Index-Fund-9-4-11.pdf.

  • Bogle, J.C. (2014) “Lightning Strikes: The Creation of Vanguard, the First Index Mutual Fund, and the Revolution It Spawned,” Journal of Portfolio Management, 40: 42–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane, J.H. (1999) “New Facts in Finance,” Economic Perspectives, 23: 36–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dimson, E., P. Marsh and M. Staunton (2002) Triumph of the Optimists: 101 Years of Global Investment Returns. Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dimson, E., P. Marsh and M. Staunton (2018) Credit Suisse Global Investment Returns Yearbook 2018. Zurich, Credit Suisse Research Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F. (1970) “Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work,” Journal of Finance, 25: 383–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E.F. and K.R. French (1988) “Permanent and Temporary Components of Stock Prices,” Journal of Political Economy, 96: 246–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mallaby, S. (2010) More Money Than God: Hedge Funds and the Making of a New Elite. New York, Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehra, R. and E.C. Prescott (1985) “The Equity Premium: A Puzzle,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 15: 145–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R.C. (1969) “An Empirical Investigation of the Samuelson Rational Warrant Pricing Theory,” class paper, included as Chapter V in Analytical Optimal Control Theory as Applied to Stochastic and Non-Stochastic Economics. Unpublished PhD dissertation (1970), MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R.C. (1983) “Financial Economics,” in E.C. Brown and R.M. Solow (eds.) Paul Samuelson and Modern Economic Theory. New York, McGraw Hill: 105–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton, R.C. (2006) “Paul Samuelson and Financial Economics,” American Economist, 50: 9–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani, F. and R.A. Cohn (1979) “Inflation, Rational Valuation and the Market,” Financial Analysts Journal, 35: 24–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J.M. and L.H. Summers (1988) “Mean Reversion in Stock Returns: Evidence and Implications,” Journal of Financial Economics, 22: 27–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • S&P Dow Jones Indices (2016) “SPIVA Institutional Scorecard – How Much Do Fees Affect the Active Versus Passive Debate?” July. Available at https://us.spindices.com/documents/research/research-spiva-institutional-scorecard-how-much-do-fees-affect-the-active-versus-passive-debate.pdf.

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1937) “Some Aspects of the Pure Theory of Capital,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 51: 469–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1948) Economics. First edition. New York, McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1963) “Risk and Uncertainty: A Fallacy of Large Numbers,” Scientia, 57: 108–113.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1965a) “Rational Theory of Warrant Pricing,” Industrial Management Review, 6: 13–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1965b) “Proof That Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly,” Industrial Management Review, 6: 41–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1973) The Samuelson Sampler. Glen Ridge, NJ, T. Horton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1974) “Challenge to Judgment,” Journal of Portfolio Management, 1: 17–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1976) “Index-Fund Investing,” Newsweek, 16 August: 66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1989a) “The Judgment of Economic Science on Rational Portfolio Management: Indexing, Timing, and Long-Horizon Effects,” Journal of Portfolio Management, 16: 4–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P.A. (1989b) “The √N Law and Repeated Risktaking,” in T.W. Anderson, K.B. Athreya and D.L. Iglehart (eds.) Probability, Statistics, and Mathematics: Papers in Honor of Samuel Karlin. San Diego, CA and Orlando, FL, Academic Press: 291–306.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P.A. (1991) “Long-Run Risk Tolerance When Equity Returns Are Mean Progressing: Pseudoparadoxes and Vindication of ‘Businessman’s Risk’,” in W.C. Brainard, W.D. Nordhaus and H.W. Watts (eds.) Money, Macroeconomics, and Economic Policy. Cambridge, MA, The MIT Press: 181–204.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P.A. (1992) “At Last, a Rational Case for Long-Horizon Risk Tolerance and for Asset-Allocation Timing?” in R.D. Arnold and F.J. Fabozzi (eds.) Active Asset Allocation: State-of-the-Art Portfolio Policies, Strategies & Tactics. Chicago, Probus Publishing: 411–416.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1993) “Reflections on Investing for Foundations and Colleges,” Rutgers Conference, New York, 17 November.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (1994) “The Long-Term Case for Equities (And How It Can Be Oversold),” Journal of Portfolio Management, 21: 15–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P.A. (1997) “Dogma of the Decade: Sure-Thing Risk Erosion for Long-Horizon Investors,” originally published as “Dogma of the Day”), Bloomberg Personal, 33–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P.A. (2005) “Franco: A Mind Never at Rest,” BNL Quarterly Review, 58: 5–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P.A. (2009) “An Enjoyable Life Puzzling Over Modern Finance Theory,” Annual Review of Financial Economics, 1: 19–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P.A. (2010) “On the Himalayan Shoulders of Harry Markowitz,” in J.B. Guerard (ed.) Handbook of Portfolio Construction: Contemporary Applications of Markowitz Techniques. New York, Springer: 125–132.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R.J. (1981) “Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to Be Justified by Subsequent Changes in Dividends?” American Economic Review, 71: 421–436.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R.J. (1984) “Stock Prices and Social Dynamics,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 457–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, J.J. (1992) “The Equity Premium: Stock and Bond Returns Since 1802,” Financial Analysts Journal, 48: 28–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, J.J. (1994) Stocks for the Long Run. First edition. Burr Ridge, IL, Irwin Professional Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, J.J. (2014) Stocks for the Long Run. Fifth edition. New York, McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author is the Russell Palmer Professor of Finance at the Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania and a student of Paul Samuelson from 1967 through 1971. I would like to thank Robert Cord for offering me the opportunity to write about this iconic economist and Michal Kolakowski for valuable research support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jeremy J. Siegel .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Siegel, J.J. (2019). Climbing Mount Everest: Paul Samuelson on Financial Theory and Practice. In: Cord, R., Anderson, R., Barnett, W. (eds) Paul Samuelson. Remaking Economics: Eminent Post-War Economists. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-56812-0_13

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-56812-0_13

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-137-56811-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-137-56812-0

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics