Skip to main content

Signalling Control

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: European Administrative Governance ((EAGOV))

Abstract

This chapter develops a novel survey instrument that measures not only the frequency with which national representatives use a range of signalling tactics, but also the phase in the negotiating process at which such signalling takes place. Nearly forty representatives from the Council working parties filled in the survey, permitting a comprehensive analysis of national involvement in the EU’s trade negotiations. Analysis of the data confirms that there is substantive variation in the amount of control member states exert, and that variation may be explained by administrative capacity. This chapter also reveals that respondents’ signalling strategy is not determined by the size of their country but rather by the stage in the negotiating process at which they are particularly active.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Soft bargaining is characterised by co-operative or friendly behaviour, whereas hard bargaining strategies relate to conflicting or aggressive tactics. Based on this distinction Dür and Mateo were able to formulate a number of actions—or tactics—that can unambiguously be interpreted both by respondents and researchers (Dür & Mateo, 2010b).

  2. 2.

    Other scholars have often distinguished between a pre-negotiation, negotiation, and post-negotiation phase (Elgström, Larsén, & Frennhoff Larsén, 2010). Surely, the six phases can easily be aggregated by three consecutive pairs to match such a conceptualisation. The advantage of the proposed demarcation, however, enables a clear separation of a proactive and a reactive stage while at the same time allowing for the distinction between the formal and informal stages of control.

  3. 3.

    Briefly formulated, the like-minded group is an informal coalition of member states advocating a more liberal trade agenda. The “open-minded” group by contrast is more pragmatic and favours the use of trade protection when it is deemed necessary.

  4. 4.

    Influence analysis (through dfbeta’s) when studying the main hypothesis (see Chap. 7) also singled out these respondents as suspicious. More information can be found in Annex A3 (3).

  5. 5.

    The internal consistency of the different indicators revealed an alpha of 0.76, which is acceptable and close to the mean and median values obtained in past survey research (Peterson, 1994).

  6. 6.

    The items of the index were first rescaled to [0,5] by subtracting one from all values. Such rescaling also occurred in the construction of other indicators (see infra).The resulting scores were then averaged and multiplied by 20.

  7. 7.

    The indicator takes into account the latest enlargement with Croatia, values were derived from Napel et al. (2013).

  8. 8.

    These differences were significant in a matched t-test and Wilcoxon matched pairs signed rank test.

  9. 9.

    For this variable, the following formula was used: Proactive (added) = 10 . (15 + P − R)/3. A respondent will obtain a score of 100 only if she/he has given the highest value on each of the proactive stages, while attributing the lowest possible scores to the reactive stages (P = 15; R = 0). A value of 50 will occur when P equals R. Unlike the ratio based indicator, for this measure it matters whether a respondent attributed a high or low score to the different stages.

  10. 10.

    To calculate the number of required replications, one can also use the three-step approach (Andrews & Buchinsky, 2000). The minimum number of replications as reported by STATA’s “bssize” procedure (Poi, 2004) were well below 5000 in the cases tested.

  11. 11.

    Of the thirty-seven respondents that answered this question, twenty-seven responded “regularly.” Of the remaining ten, six responded “rarely,” and the final four indicated “frequently.” The other answering options were not being used.

References

  • Andrews, D. W. K. & Buchinsky, M. (2000). A three-step method for choosing the number of bootstrap repetitions. Econometrica, 68(1), 23–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Börzel, T. A. (2002). Pace-setting, foot-dragging, and fence-sitting: Member state responses to Europeanization. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies, 40(2), 193–214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cross, J. P. (2012). Interventions and negotiation in the Council of Ministers of the European Union. European Union Politics, 13(1), 47–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cross, J. P. (2013). Everyone’s a winner (almost): Bargaining success in the Council of Ministers of the European Union. European Union Politics, 14(1), 70–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crump, L. (2011). Negotiation process and negotiation context. International Negotiation, 16(2), 197–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Ville, F. & Siles Brugge, G. (2015). The truth about TTIP. Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dür, A. & Mateo, G. (2010a). Bargaining power and negotiation tactics: The negotiations on the EU’s Financial Perspective, 2007–13. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies, 48(3), 557–578.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dür, A. & Mateo, G. (2010b). Choosing a bargaining strategy in EU negotiations: Power, preferences, and culture. Journal of European Public Policy, 17(5), 680–693.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Efron, B. (1979). Bootstrap methods: Another look at the jackknife. The Annals of Statistics, 7(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egeberg, M., Gornitzka, Å., Trondal, J., & Johannessen, M. (2013). Parliament staff: Unpacking the behaviour of officials in the European Parliament. Journal of European Public Policy, 20(4), 495–514.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elgström, O. & Jönsson, C. (2000). Negotiation in the European Union: Bargaining or problem-solving? Journal of European Public Policy, 7(5), 684–704.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elgström, O., Bjurulf, B., Johansson, J., & Sannerstedt, A. (2001). Coalitions in European Union Negotiations. Scandinavian Political Studies, 24(2), 111–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elgström, O., Larsén, M. F., & Frennhoff Larsén, M. (2010). Free to trade? Commission autonomy in the Economic Partnership Agreement negotiations. Journal of European Public Policy, 17(2), 205–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elsig, M. (2010). European Union trade policy after enlargement: Larger crowds, shifting priorities and informal decision-making. Journal of European Public Policy, 17(6), 781–798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fox, J. (2008). Bootstrapping Regression Models. In Applied regression analysis and generalized linear models (pp. 587–606). Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE Publications Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gastinger, M. (forthcoming). The tables have turned on the European Commission: The changing nature of the pre-negotiation phase in EU bilateral trade agreements. Journal of European Public Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greer, S. & Martin de Almagro, M. (2012). Being Spain in Brussels: Policy bureaucracy, agenda setting and negotiation in the EU policy process. International Journal of Iberian Studies, 24(2), 71–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haverland, M. & Liefferink, D. (2012a). Member State interest articulation in the Commission phase. Institutional pre-conditions for influencing “Brussels.”. Journal of European Public Policy, 19(2), 179–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haverland, M. & Liefferink, D. (2012b). Member State interest articulation in the Commission phase. Institutional pre-conditions for influencing “Brussels.”. Journal of European Public Policy, 19(2), 179–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L. (2005). Several roads lead to international norms, but few via international socialization: A case study of the European Commission. International Organization, 59(04), 861–898.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hosli, M. O. (1999). Power, connected coalitions, and efficiency: Challenges to the Council of the European Union. International Political Science Review, 20(4), 371–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jonsson, C. & Tallberg, J. (1998). Compliance and post-agreement bargaining. European Journal of International Relations, 4(4), 371–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaeding, M. & Seck, T. J. (2005). Mapping Out Political Europe: Coalition patterns in EU decision-making. International Political Science Review, 26(3), 271–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lax, D. A. & Sebenius, J. K. (1986). The manager as negotiator: Bargaining for cooperation and competitive gain. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maes, I. & Verdun, A. (2005). Small states and the creation of EMU: Belgium and the Netherlands, pace-setters and gate-keepers. Journal of Common Market Studies, 43(2), 327–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • March, J. G. (1955). An introduction to the theory and measurement of influence. The American Political Science Review, 49(2), 431–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meerts, P. (1997).‘Negotiating in the European Union: comparing perceptions of EU negotiators in small member states. Group Decision and Negotiation, 6(5), 463–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Napel, S., Widgrén, M., & Mayer, A. (2013). Strategic a priori power in the European Union’s Codecision Procedure Recalculated for EU28. In M. Holler & H. Nurmi (Eds.), Power, voting and voting power: 30 years after (pp. 553–571). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Naurin, D. (2009). Most common when least important: Deliberation in the European Union Council of Ministers. British Journal of Political Science, 40(01), 31–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niemann, A. (2004). Between communicative action and strategic action: The Article 113 Committee and the negotiations on the WTO Basic Telecommunications Services Agreement. Journal of European Public Policy, 11(3), 379–407.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niemann, A. (2006). Beyond problem-solving and bargaining: Genuine debate in EU External Trade Negotiations. International Negotiation, 11(3), 467–497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panke, D. (2010a). Good instructions in no time? Domestic Coordination of EU Policies in 19 Small States. West European Politics, 33(4), 770–790.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panke, D. (2010b). Small states in the European Union: Structural disadvantages in EU policy-making and counter-strategies. Journal of European Public Policy, 17(6), 799–817.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panke, D. (2011). Small states in EU negotiations: Political dwarfs or power-brokers? Cooperation and Conflict, 46(2), 123–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peterson, R. A. (1994). Meta-analysis of Cronbach’ s coefficient alpha. Journal of Consumer Research, 21(2), 381–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poi, B. P. (2004). From the help desk: Some bootstrapping techniques. Stata Journal, 4(3), 312–328.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapley, L. & Shubik, M. (1954). A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. American Political Science Review, 48(3), 787–792.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stein, J. (1988). Getting to the table: Process of international prenegotiation. International Journal, 44(2), 231–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thorhallsson, B. & Wivel, A. (2006). Small states in the European Union: What do we know and what would we like to know? Cambridge Review of International Affairs, 19(4), 651–668.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walton, R. E. & McKersie, R. B. (1965). A behavioral theory of labor negotiations (2 ed.). Ithaca, NY: ILR Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Johan Adriaensen .

Copyright information

© 2016 The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Adriaensen, J. (2016). Signalling Control. In: National Administrations in EU Trade Policy. European Administrative Governance. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-54767-5_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics