Skip to main content

Coevolution of Mind and Society

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Evolving Norms

Part of the book series: Palgrave Advances in Behavioral Economics ((PABE))

  • 487 Accesses

Abstract

Theories of institutions can be classified into two broad approaches: institutions-as-rules and institutions-as-equilibria. Institutional structures and individual actions coevolve. In order to have a complete picture of institutions in interactions between structure and agency, we need to take both approaches into consideration. In the mental dimension, institutions guide individual behavior and thought. In the emergence dimension, the equilibrium state is generated as the result of actions chosen by individual agents. The mind is endogenous to the individual’s environment, which implies that expectations are also endogenous to the individual’s environment. Shifts in mental models change individuals’ plans and actions, which, in turn, leads to institutional evolution. A key to understanding institutional evolution is an understanding of how individuals modify their mental models.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Recently, coevolution denotes very different types of interactions: biologicalcultural, ecologicaleconomic, productionconsumption, technologypreferences, behaviorinstitution, and human geneticcultural (Durham ; Gowdy 1994) 1991.

  2. 2.

    The famous ‘impartial spectator,’ a hypothetical ‘man within the breast,’ helps us to look at the various needs and to determine what, in each situation, is the proper balance between our needs and those of others.

  3. 3.

    Children as young as 3 years can appreciate the difference between mental and physical entities (Wellman and Estes 1986 ).

  4. 4.

    Akerlof and Dickens ( 1982 ) constitute the model of cognitive dissonance in economics. In their model, agents select their beliefs to minimize the dissonance experienced.

  5. 5.

    Martin and Sunley ( 2012 ) consider three orders of emergence in economic geography. Specifically, second-order emergence is said to be characteristic of self-organizing systems. Second-order emergence is characterized by the emergence of self-organized macro-level morphology arising from the recursive amplifying interactions among the micro components.

  6. 6.

    Searle ( 2005 ) claims that an institution is any system of constitutive rules of the form ‘X counts as Y in C,’ where X is a pre-institutional entity, Y is a status function, and C refers to the domain of application of the rule.

  7. 7.

    Within Austrian economics, emergence is typically conflated with the notion of spontaneous order (Harper and Lewis 2012 ; Rosser 2012 ). Austrian economists use the concept of emergence to explain how the interplay between the actions of numerous, independent individuals can generate an order which is not part of anyone’s intentions.

  8. 8.

    In Crawford and Ostrom ( 1995 ), Lewis ( 1969 ), Ullmann-Margalit ( 1977 ), and Coleman ( 1987 ) are characterized as an institutions-as-norms approach. This approach assumes that many observed patterns of interaction are based upon the shared perceptions among a group of individuals of proper and improper behavior in particular situations.

  9. 9.

    In Vanderschraaf ( 1995 ), Lewis’ ( 1969 ) conventions are shown to be correlated equilibria.

  10. 10.

    For Hodgson, the phenomena that link agency and institutional structure are habits and processes of habituation. Habits themselves are formed through repetition of action and thought.

  11. 11.

    In Aoki ( 2007 ), the following conceptualization of an institution is proposed: “An institution is self-sustaining, salient patterns of social interactions, as represented by meaningful rules that every agent knows and are incorporated an agent’s shared belief about how the game is played and to be played” (Aoki 2007 , p. 6).

Bibliography

  • Akerlof, G. A. & Dickens, W. T. (1982). The economic consequences of cognitive dissonance. American Economic Review, 72, 307–319.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki, M. (2001). Towards a comparative institutional analysis. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki, M. (2007). Endogenizing institutions and institutional changes. Journal of Institutional Economics, 3, 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aoki, M. (2011). Institutions as cognitive media between strategic interactions and individual beliefs. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 79, 20–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann, R. J. (1974). Subjectivity and correlation in randomized strategies. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 1, 67–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann, R. J. (1987). Correlated equilibrium as an expression of Bayesian rationality. Econometrica, 55, 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aumann, R. J. & Brandenburger, A. (1995). Epistemic conditions for Nash equilibrium. Econometrica, 63, 1161–1180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. (1997). The dissemination of culture: A model with local convergence and global polarization. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41, 203–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron-Cohen, S. (1995). Mindblindness: An essay on autism and theory of mind. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, J. W. (2005). Acculturation: Living successfully in two cultures. International Journal of Intercultural Relations, 29, 697–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, R. & Richerson, P. J. (1985). Culture and the evolutionary process. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell, B. (2000). The emergence of Hayek’s ideas on cultural evolution. Review of Austrian Economics, 13, 5–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. (1987). Norms as social capital. In G. Radnitzky & P. Bernholz (Eds.), Economic imperialism. New York: Paragon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, S. & Ostrom, E. (1995). A grammar of institutions. American Political Science Review, 89, 582–600.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunbar, R. I. M. (1992). Neocortex size as a constraint on group size in primates. Journal of Human Evolution, 22, 469–493.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunbar, R. I. M. (1998). The social brain hypothesis. Evolutionary Anthropology, 6, 178–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durham, W. H. (1991). Coevolution: Genes, culture, and human diversity. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Festinger, L. (1957). A theory of cognitive dissonance. Evanston: Row, Peterson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frith, U. & Frith, C. (2001). The biological basis of social interaction. Current Directions in Psychological Science, 10, 151–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallese, V., Fadiga, L., Fogassi, L., & Rizzolatti, G. (1996). Action recognition in the premotor cortex. Brain, 119, 593–609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallese, V. & Goldman, A. (1998). Mirror neurons and the simulation theory of mind-reading. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 2, 493–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gowdy, J. M. (1994). Coevolutionary economics: The economy, society and the environment. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. & Kingston, C. (2011). Institutions: Rules or equilibria? In N. Schofield & G. Caballero (Eds.), Political economy of institutions, democracy and voting (pp. 13–43). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Harper, D. A. & Lewis, P. (2012). New perspectives on emergence in economics. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 82, 329–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1948). Individualism and economic order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1952). The sensory order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. ([1952] 1979). The counter-revolution of science, 2nd ed. Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Press. Original Work Published 1952.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1973). Law, legislation and liberty, Vol. 1, Rules and order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1979). Law, legislation and liberty, Vol. 3, The political order of a free people. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1988). The fatal conceit: The errors of socialism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (2014). The collected works of F. A. Hayek, Vol. 15, The markets and other orders. In B. Caldwell (Ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrmann, E., Call, J., Hernández-Lloreda, M. V., Hare, B., & Tomasello, M. (2007). Humans have evolved specialized skills of social cognition: The cultural intelligence hypothesis. Science, 317, 1360–1366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. M. (2004). The evolution of institutional economics: Agency, structure, and darwinism in American Institutionalism. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Keysar, B., Lin, S., & Barr, D. J. (2003). Limits on theory of mind in adults. Cognition, 89, 25–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1970). The legacy of Max Weber. London: Heinnemann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1976). From Mises to Shackle: An essay on Austrian economics and the Kaleidic society. Journal of Economic Literature, 14, 54–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. P. (1999a). Culture and language. Journal of Political Economy, 107, S95–S126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, D. (1969). Convention: A philosophical study. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, R. & Sunley, P. (2012). Forms of emergence and the evolution of economic landscapes. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 82, 338–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. (1995). Recent evolutionary theorizing about economic change. Journal of Economic Literature, 33, 48–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. R. & Winter, S. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norgaard, R. B. (1994). Development betrayed: The end of progress and a coevolutionary revisioning of the future. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Povinelli, D. J. & Giambrone, S. (2001). Reasoning about beliefs: A human specialization? Child Development, 72, 691–695.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rizzello, S., & Turvani, M. (2000). Institutions meet mind: The way out of an impasse. Constitutional Political Economy, 11, 165–180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rizzello, S. & Turvani, M. (2002). Subjective diversity and social learning: A cognitive perspective for understanding institutional behavior. Constitutional Political Economy, 13, 197–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rizzolatti, G. & Craighero, L. (2004). The mirror-neuron system. Annual Review of Neuroscience, 27, 169–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rizzolatti, G. & Craighero, L. (2005). Mirror neurons: A neurological approach to empathy. In J.-P. Changeux, A. R. Damasio, W. Singer, & Y. Christen (Eds.), Neurobiology of human values (pp. 107–123). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rizzolatti, G., Fadiga, L., Gallese, V., & Fogassi, L. (1996). Premotor cortex and the recognition of motor actions. Cognitive Brain Research, 3, 131–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rizzolatti, G., Fogassi, L., & Galllese, V. (2001). Neurophysiological mexhanisms underlying the understanding and imitation of action. Nature Reviews Neuroscience, 2, 661–670.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosser Jr., J. B. (2012). Emergence and complexity in Austrian economics. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81, 122–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schotter, A. (1981). The Economic theory of social institutions. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Searle, J. R. (2005). What is an institution? Journal of Institutional Economics, 1, 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ullmann-Margalit, E. (1977). The Emergence of norms. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vanderschraaf, P. (1995). Convention as correlated equilibrium. Erkenntnis, 42(1), 65–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wellman, H. M. & Estes, D. (1986). Early understanding of mental entities: A reexamination of childhood realism. Child Development, 57, 910–923.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 2016 The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Teraji, S. (2016). Coevolution of Mind and Society. In: Evolving Norms. Palgrave Advances in Behavioral Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, New York. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-50247-6_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-50247-6_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, New York

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-137-50246-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-137-50247-6

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics