Skip to main content

Lending of Last Resort and Supervision

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover The Evolution of Central Banking: Theory and History

Part of the book series: Palgrave Studies in Economic History ((PEHS))

  • 1403 Accesses

Abstract

The banking sector is inherently fragile as it is plagued by a number of market failures (especially those due to information asymmetries); its heavy regulation is justified by the large negative externalities generated by bank failures. Regulatory tools include both ex-ante interventions (legislation and supervision) and ex-post interventions (lending of last resort, bailouts, and deposit insurance). Historically, heavy regulatory frameworks featuring rule-based ex-ante interventions have prevailed in some contexts (e.g. early modern Venice and nineteenth-century United States), while light-touch regulatory frameworks featuring discretionary ex-post interventions have prevailed in other contexts (e.g. nineteenth-century Europe). The heritage of these diverging approaches is still well visible today, as national regulatory frameworks continue to differ substantially.

We have a number of recent examples in our memory (or better, still before our eyes) of the turmoil and great harm that bank failures have inflicted to this city. Noble and affluent houses have been decayed and extinguished; many citizens have been reduced to extreme poverty or greatly battered; unmarried women have been left with no dowry, widows with no subsidy, orphans with no sustenance; merchants have been left weakened, business disordered, and public revenues diminished. […] Which does not happen without somewhat discrediting the state: as in view of the fact that banks had been authorised by decree and continuously supervised by a specifically-appointed and fully-dedicated body, one is led to believe that accidents and failures could not develop without the administration being aware of that.

Tommaso Contarini , Speech to the Venetian Senate in Support of the Creation of a Public Bank, 28 December 1584 (quoted in Lattes (1869, p. 123), my translation and emphasis).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Debreu (1959). On the Arrow-Debreu model and its limits as a heuristic device, see Bowles and Gintis (1993).

  2. 2.

    Freixas and Rochet (2008, pp. 15–20 and 146–153).

  3. 3.

    Freixas and Rochet (2008, pp. 4–5).

  4. 4.

    Bank for International Settlements (2016).

  5. 5.

    See, for example, Jacklin (1987).

  6. 6.

    Diamond (1984); Holmström and Tirole (1997).

  7. 7.

    Calomiris and Kahn (1991); Flannery (1994). A completely opposite view is held by Dewatripont and Tirole (1994, pp. 29–45), according to whom the prime motivation for banking regulation is precisely the fact that lenders are very ill-placed to monitor banks.

  8. 8.

    Diamond and Rajan (2001).

  9. 9.

    See, for example, Grossman (2010, pp. 16–27).

  10. 10.

    Bryant (1980); Diamond and Dybvig (1983).

  11. 11.

    Goodfriend (1991, pp. 11–12).

  12. 12.

    Kahn and Roberds (2002).  For a definition of finality, see Sect. 2.1.1.

  13. 13.

    De Young and Rice (2004).

  14. 14.

    Allen and Gale (2000, pp. 9–10).

  15. 15.

    Freixas and Santomero (2003).

  16. 16.

    A more cynical view (inspired by public choice theory) holds that banking regulation is ubiquitous not because regulators aim at solving market failures , but because they aim at extracting rents : according to this view, because banking would not even be possible without regulatory intervention, extraction is particularly easy in this sector (Calomiris and Haber 2014, pp. 28–34). This view, however, is narrowly focused on limited liability banks. In fact, banking instability and regulation largely predated the introduction of joint-stock banking (see Sect. 3.2.1).

  17. 17.

    Diamond and Dybvig (1983); Postlewaite and Vives (1987).

  18. 18.

    Rochet and Vives (2004).

  19. 19.

    Flannery (1996); Allen and Gale (2000, pp. 282–294).

  20. 20.

    Fetter (1965, pp. 21–23).

  21. 21.

    Grossman and Rockoff (2016, pp. 255–256).

  22. 22.

    Thornton (1802).

  23. 23.

    Hawtrey (1932).

  24. 24.

    Humphrey and Keleher (1984).

  25. 25.

    Bagehot (1873).

  26. 26.

    See esp. Kindleberger (1978).

  27. 27.

    Reference here is to the vast theoretical literature inspired by the modelling of banking panics first proposed by Diamond and Dybvig (1983).

  28. 28.

    “Money will not manage itself” (Bagehot 1873, p. 20).

  29. 29.

    “The peculiar essence of our banking system is an unprecedented trust between man and man: and when that trust is much weakened by hidden causes, a small accident may greatly hurt it, and a great accident for a moment may almost destroy it” (Bagehot 1873, pp. 158–159).

  30. 30.

    “These considerations enable us to estimate the responsibility which is thrown on the Bank of England by our system , and by every system on the bank or banks who by it keep the reserve of bullion or of legal tender exchangeable for bullion ” (Bagehot 1873, p. 121).

  31. 31.

    Bignon et al. (2012).

  32. 32.

    “The public is never sure what policy will be adopted at the most important moment: it is not sure what amount of advance will be made, or on what security it will be made. The best palliative to a panic is a confidence in the adequate amount of the Bank reserve , and in the efficient use of that reserve. And until we have on this point a clear understanding with the Bank of England , both our liability to crises and our terror at crises will always be greater than they would otherwise be” (Bagehot 1873, pp. 206–207).

  33. 33.

    “If it is known that the Bank of England is freely advancing on what in ordinary times is reckoned a good security —on what is then commonly pledged and easily convertible—the alarm of the solvent merchants and bankers will be stayed. But if securities, really good and usually convertible, are refused by the Bank, the alarm will not abate, the other loans made will fail in obtaining their end, and the panic will become worse and worse” (Bagehot 1873, p. 198).

  34. 34.

    “The end is to stay the panic ; and the advances should, if possible, stay the panic. And for this purpose there are two rules :—First. That these loans should only be made at a very high rate of interest . This will operate as a heavy fine on unreasonable timidity, and will prevent the greatest number of applications by persons who do not require it. The rate should be raised early in the panic, so that the fine may be paid early; that no one may borrow out of idle precaution without paying well for it” (Bagehot 1873, p. 197).

  35. 35.

    “But if the Bank had not made these advances, could it have kept its reserve ? Certainly it could not. It could not have retained its own deposits . A large part of these are the deposits of bankers , and they would not consent to help the Bank of England in a policy of isolation. They would not agree to suspend payments themselves, and permit the Bank of England to survive, and get all their business. They would withdraw their deposits from the Bank; they would not assist it to stand erect amid their ruin” (Bagehot 1873, p. 191).

  36. 36.

    Note that Bagehot thought that such a structure was suboptimal (it was the outcome of government intervention in the sector, which had produced the Bank of England ’s monopolistic position ) and inferior to free banking : “I believe that our system , though curious and peculiar, may be worked safely; but if we wish so to work it, we must study it. We must not think we have an easy task when we have a difficult task, or that we are living in a natural state when we are really living in an artificial one” (Bagehot 1873, p. 20).

  37. 37.

    See, for example, Laidler (2004).

  38. 38.

    Goodfriend and King (1988). Freixas et al. (2004) clarify the argument within a rigorous theoretical framework and find some scope for central bank lending to individual banks, but only under very restrictive conditions.

  39. 39.

    Goodhart (1999, pp. 345–346). The flipside of the coin is that potentially troubled banks face disincentives to approach the central bank for fear of providing bad signals —a phenomenon known as discount window stigma . See Sect. 3.2.3.

  40. 40.

    See, for example, Gorton (1988).

  41. 41.

    Hankey (1867).

  42. 42.

    For a survey, see Moore (1999).

  43. 43.

    Solow (1982) was the first to describe the discount window as an insurance facility on banks’ assets, that is, as something economically akin to deposit insurance . In parallel, deposit insurance was described as a put option by Merton (1977).

  44. 44.

    See, for example, Sleet and Smith (2000) or Freixas et al. (2004). This conclusion is disputed by others, for example, Castiglionesi and Wagner (2012).

  45. 45.

    Goodfriend and King (1988).

  46. 46.

    Martin (2009).

  47. 47.

    See, for example, Flannery (1996) or Antinolfi et al. (2001).

  48. 48.

    Allen and Gale (2017).

  49. 49.

    To be precise, Bagehot recommended the Bank of England to extend both secur itized and non-securitized loans : the former consisted of advances on exchange-traded securities, while the latter consisted of discounts of bills of exchang e. Bills of exchange were idiosyncratic, uncollateralized certificates of corporate indebtedness with multiple guarantee s (see Sect. 2.2.3). They were bought outright by the Bank’s discount window and never reinjected onto the market: Flandreau and Ugolini (2013). Bagehot ’s recommendations under this respect have sometimes been slightly misrepresented by later commentators, who have often translated them as lending on collateral “which is marketable in the ordinary course of business”: see, for example, Hogan et al. (2015).

  50. 50.

    Gorton and Ordoñez (2014).

  51. 51.

    For a survey of this literature, see Allen and Gale (2017).

  52. 52.

    See, for example, Rochet and Vives (2004); Goldstein and Pauzner (2005).

  53. 53.

    See, for example, Morris and Shin (2016). Note that the commonplace translation of the second Bagehot rule as “lend to illiquid but solvent banks” is not truly faithful to the author’s view, as Bagehot was aware of the reverse causation link between illiquidity and insolvency : “The evil is, that owing to terror, what is commonly good security has ceased to be so; and the true policy is so to use the Banking reserve , that if possible the temporary evil may be stayed, and the common course of business be restored”: Bagehot (1873, p. 205), my emphasis.

  54. 54.

    Repullo (2005); Martin (2006).

  55. 55.

    Goodhart (1999, pp. 348–352); Archer and Moser-Boehm (2013).

  56. 56.

    Gorton and Ordoñez (2014); Hogan et al. (2015).

  57. 57.

    The concept of “market-maker of last resort ” has been first popularized by Buiter and Sibert (2007).

  58. 58.

    Mehrling (2011, pp. 23–29 and 132–135).

  59. 59.

    Hogan et al. (2015, pp. 343–345). Note that in his early criticism of Bagehot’s proposals, Hankey argued that they could have been conducive to moral hazard because they entailed distributional effects not within the financial sector, but between the financial sector and other economic sectors (Hankey 1867, pp. 29–30). To this, Bagehot replied that Hankey’s argument was irrelevant, as the intervention he advocated largely consisted of direct lending to the real sector (not to the financial sector) through the discount of bills of exchange issued by all kinds of firms (Bagehot 1873, p. 172).

  60. 60.

    See Sects. 3.2.1 and 3.2.2.

  61. 61.

    See, for example, Humphrey (2010) or Bordo (2014).

  62. 62.

    “Any aid to a present bad bank is the surest mode of preventing the establishment of a future good bank”: Bagehot (1873, p. 104).

  63. 63.

    See, for example, Rochet and Vives (2004); Farhi and Tirole (2012); or Keister (2016).

  64. 64.

    The term “too-big-to-fail ” was apparently coined in 1984 by Congressman Stewart McKinney in connection to the bailout of Continental Illinois (Gorton 2012, p. 146).

  65. 65.

    Allen and Babus (2009).

  66. 66.

    For surveys, see Chinazzi and Fagiolo (2015) and Hüser (2015).

  67. 67.

    For a survey, see Bongini and Nieri (2014).

  68. 68.

    Brewer and Jagtiani (2013).

  69. 69.

    Some authors even consider that in the absence of “explicit” (i.e. formal) deposit insurance schemes, “implicit” deposit insurance always exists because of the government commitment to organize the bailout of failing banks: see, for example, Demirgüç-Kunt et al. (2015).

  70. 70.

    This is the design adopted in most countries: deposit insurance schemes are mostly funded ex-ante by banks and provided by a fiscal backstop (e.g. a Treasury credit line ) in case of insufficient funding. Exceptions exist, though. For a complete overview, see Demirgüç-Kunt et al. (2015).

  71. 71.

    Diamond and Dybvig (1983).

  72. 72.

    Demirgüç-Kunt et al. (2015).

  73. 73.

    Merton (1977).

  74. 74.

    Dam and Koetter (2012).

  75. 75.

    Laeven (2002).

  76. 76.

    For a survey, see Santos (2006).

  77. 77.

    Calomiris et al. (2016).

  78. 78.

    See, for example, Repullo (2000); Kahn and Santos (2005).

  79. 79.

    See, for example, Boyer and Ponce (2012); Barth et al. (2012, pp. 219–220).

  80. 80.

    Goodhart and Schoenmaker (1995).

  81. 81.

    Blinder (2010).

  82. 82.

    For a survey, see Masciandaro and Quintyn (2016).

  83. 83.

    See, for example, Grossman (2010), Turner (2014), or Calomiris and Haber (2014).

  84. 84.

    Freshfield (1938).

  85. 85.

    Note that unlimited liability can in itself be interpreted as a barrier to entry : Carr and Mathewson (1988).

  86. 86.

    See Sect. 2.2.1.

  87. 87.

    Mueller (1997, pp. 36–37).

  88. 88.

    Lattes (1869, pp. 13–15 and 20); Ferrara (1871, pp. 444–446).

  89. 89.

    By contrast, bankers’ cash reserves kept (for safekeeping purposes) in the Treasury ’s safes at Palazzo dei Camerlenghi could be frozen in case of failure and thus used to repay depositors: Mueller (1997, pp. 52–61 and 71–72).

  90. 90.

    See Sect. 2.2.1.

  91. 91.

    Mueller (1997, pp. 151–153).

  92. 92.

    Ferrara (1871, pp. 184–188).

  93. 93.

    Ferrara (1871, pp. 446–449).

  94. 94.

    Ferrara (1871, pp. 449–451).

  95. 95.

    See Sect. 2.2.1.

  96. 96.

    See Sect. 2.2.3.

  97. 97.

    Mueller (1997, pp. 67–69).

  98. 98.

    Mueller (1997, pp. 125–168).

  99. 99.

    Lattes (1869, pp. 14–15).

  100. 100.

    Ferrara (1871, pp. 458–466). On the concept of “financial repression ”, see McKinnon (1973, pp. 68–77).

  101. 101.

    Mueller (1997, pp. 126–128 and 163–168).

  102. 102.

    Lattes (1869, pp. 15–17).

  103. 103.

    Lattes (1869, p. 15).

  104. 104.

    Ferrara (1871, pp. 204–211).

  105. 105.

    Lattes (1869, pp. 15–16).

  106. 106.

    Lattes (1869, pp. 16–17).

  107. 107.

    Lattes (1869, pp. 18–20).

  108. 108.

    Lattes (1869, p. 17).

  109. 109.

    Mueller (1997, pp. 126–127). On the role of Mints as lenders of last resort , also see the case of early modern Ragusa (Dubrovnik) : Pierucci (1991).

  110. 110.

    See Sect. 2.2.2.

  111. 111.

    Schnabel and Shin (2004).

  112. 112.

    Quinn and Roberds (2015).

  113. 113.

    Uittenbogaard (2009, pp. 127–131).

  114. 114.

    See Sect. 2.2.4.

  115. 115.

    Richards (1929, pp. 146–147 and 191–192).

  116. 116.

    Pressnell (1956).

  117. 117.

    See Sect. 2.2.4.

  118. 118.

    Turner (2014, pp. 108–109).

  119. 119.

    Cottrell (2010).

  120. 120.

    Turner (2014, pp. 123–126).

  121. 121.

    Turner (2014, pp. 120–133).

  122. 122.

    Pressnell (1968).

  123. 123.

    Ugolini (2016).

  124. 124.

    Cottrell (2010).

  125. 125.

    Pressnell (1968).

  126. 126.

    Ugolini (2016).

  127. 127.

    Turner (2014, pp. 6–12).

  128. 128.

    Uittenbogaard (2009).

  129. 129.

    Clapham (1944, I, pp. 300–302).

  130. 130.

    Lovell (1957).

  131. 131.

    See Sects. 2.2.3 and 2.2.4.

  132. 132.

    Clapham (1944, I, pp. 300–302).

  133. 133.

    Clapham (1944, II, pp. 93–102).

  134. 134.

    Wood (1939, pp. 90–95).

  135. 135.

    King (1936, pp. 62–70).

  136. 136.

    Wood (1939, pp. 101–103).

  137. 137.

    Clapham (1944, II, pp. 187–189).

  138. 138.

    Wood (1939, pp. 135–143).

  139. 139.

    Bignon et al. (2012).

  140. 140.

    Fetter (1965, pp. 257–258 and 282–283).

  141. 141.

    Hankey (1867, pp. 25–30).

  142. 142.

    “Ready money is a most valuable thing; it cannot from its very essence bear interest  – every one is therefore constantly endeavouring to make it profitable , and at the same time to make it retain its use as ready money, which is simply impossible. Turn it into whatever shape you please, it can never be made into more real capital than is due to its own intrinsic value, and it is the constant attempt to perform this miracle which leads to all sorts of confusion with respect to credit. The Bank of England has been long expected to assist in performing this miracle; and it is the attempt to force the Bank to do so which has led to the greater number of the difficulties which have occurred on every occasion of monetary panics during the last twenty years”: Hankey (1867, p. 25). Note that Bagehot based the whole of his argument precisely on the positive observation that, for historical reasons, the Bank of England had come to centralize the country ’s reserves of cash —which was, to him, an inferior situation to free banking from a normative viewpoint: Bagehot (1873, p. 20).

  143. 143.

    Ugolini (2016).

  144. 144.

    Tamagna (1963, pp. 98–99).

  145. 145.

    Fetter (1965, pp. 272–275).

  146. 146.

    Bignon et al. (2012).

  147. 147.

    See Sect. 2.2.3.

  148. 148.

    See Sect. 2.2.3.

  149. 149.

    Flandreau and Ugolini (2013).

  150. 150.

    Flandreau and Ugolini (2014, pp. 87–89).

  151. 151.

    See Sect. 2.2.4.

  152. 152.

    Flores (2011).

  153. 153.

    Chapman (1984, pp. 32–33 and 121–122).

  154. 154.

    Ugolini (2014).

  155. 155.

    Clapham (1944, II, pp. 328–339).

  156. 156.

    Roberts (2013); Accominotti (2012).

  157. 157.

    Turner (2014, pp. 174–180).

  158. 158.

    De Cecco (1974); Roberts (2013).

  159. 159.

    Ugolini (2016).

  160. 160.

    Toniolo and White (2016, pp. 431–433 and 441–442).

  161. 161.

    Bignon et al. (2012); Hautcoeur et al. (2014).

  162. 162.

    Bignon and Avaro (2017).

  163. 163.

    Roulleau (1914, p. 41).

  164. 164.

    Toniolo and White (2016, pp. 460–461).

  165. 165.

    Jobst and Kernbauer (2016, pp. 176–186).

  166. 166.

    Toniolo and White (2016, pp. 455–467).

  167. 167.

    See Sect. 2.2.5.

  168. 168.

    Grubb (2003).

  169. 169.

    Van Fenstermaker (1965).

  170. 170.

    Leonard (1940); Macey and Miller (1992).

  171. 171.

    Rockoff (1991).

  172. 172.

    Calomiris (1990).

  173. 173.

    Taus (1943, pp. 16–57).

  174. 174.

    Timberlake (1993, pp. 47–51).

  175. 175.

    See Sect. 2.2.5.

  176. 176.

    White (1983, pp. 10–35).

  177. 177.

    Calomiris (1990).

  178. 178.

    Taus (1943, pp. 68–71, 75–76, 85–93, and 121–128).

  179. 179.

    See Sect. 2.2.5.

  180. 180.

    White (1983, pp. 95–104 and 156–167).

  181. 181.

    See esp. Warburg (1910). For an historical account, see Broz (1997).

  182. 182.

    Flandreau and Ugolini (2013).

  183. 183.

    Generally short of information on borrowers’ creditworthiness, the Feds as a rule discounted paper only up to the amount of capital of the borrowing bank, and required the pledging of additional collateral whenever the amounts discounted exceeded that sum: “As a general principle, the Federal Reserve bank takes the position that a member bank may benefit from its name up to its capital and surplus and may borrow from the Reserve or other banks to that amount without collateral , but beyond that its name is exhausted and further protection is warrantably asked. It may make exceptions of banks in which it has great confidence and lend them beyond capital and surplus without additional collateral, while to others it loans less than this amount on account of its knowledge of the condition of the bank, and the ability of their management; some of the larger banks may have credit much greater than their capital and surplus but they are secured by government bonds ”: Westerfield (1932, p. 49).

  184. 184.

    Bindseil (2004, pp. 121–126).

  185. 185.

    Calomiris et al. (2016).

  186. 186.

    Bordo and Wheelock (2013).

  187. 187.

    Eichengreen and Flandreau (2012).

  188. 188.

    Macey and Miller (1992).

  189. 189.

    Kane (1989).

  190. 190.

    Toniolo and White (2016, pp. 461–463).

  191. 191.

    Toniolo and White (2016).

  192. 192.

    Jobst and Ugolini (2016). On the standing facility features of the European Central Bank ’s liquidity -injecting operations, see Bindseil (2004, pp. 152–162).

  193. 193.

    See esp. Goodhart (1988).

Bibliography

  • O. Accominotti (2012) ‘London Merchant Banks, the Central European Panic, and the Sterling Crisis of 1931’, Journal of Economic History, LXXII, 1–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • F. Allen and A. Babus (2009) ‘Networks in Finance’ in P. R. Kleindorfer and Y. Wind (eds.) The Network Challenge: Strategy, Profit, and Risk in an Interlinked Word (Upper Saddle River: Prentice-Hall), 367–382.

    Google Scholar 

  • F. Allen and D. Gale (2000) Comparing Financial Systems (Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • F. Allen and D. Gale (2017) ‘How Should Bank Liquidity Be Regulated?’, working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • G. Antinolfi, E. Huybens, and T. Keister (2001) ‘Monetary Stability and Liquidity Crises: The Role of the Lender of Last Resort’, Journal of Economic Theory, XCIX, 187–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. Archer and P. Moser-Boehm (2013) ‘Central Bank Finances’, Bank for International Settlements Papers, 71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bank for International Settlements (2016) Glossary of Technical Terms, http://www.bis.org/statistics/glossary.htm, date accessed 4 April 2017.

  • W. Bagehot (1873) Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market (London: King).

    Google Scholar 

  • J. R. Barth, G. Caprio, and R. Levine (2012) Guardians of Finance: Making Regulators Work for Us (Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • V. Bignon and M. Avaro (2017) ‘Socially Embedded Money Creation: Monetary Policy and Bank of France Counterparty Risk Management in Late Nineteenth-Century France’, working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • V. Bignon, M. Flandreau, and S. Ugolini (2012) ‘Bagehot for Beginners: The Making of Lending-of-Last-Resort Operations in the Mid-19th Century’, Economic History Review, LXV, 580–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U. Bindseil (2004) Monetary Policy Implementation: Theory, Past, Present (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • A. S. Blinder (2010) ‘How Central Should the Central Bank Be?’, Journal of Economic Literature, XLVIII, 123–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • P. Bongini and L. Nieri (2014) ‘Identifying and Regulating Systemically Important Financial Institutions’, Economic Notes, XLIII, 39–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • M. D. Bordo (2014) ‘Rules for a Lender of Last Resort: A Historical Perspective’, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, XLIX, 126–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • M. D. Bordo and D. C. Wheelock (2013) ‘The Promise and Performance of the Federal Reserve as Lender of Last Resort, 1914–1933’ in M. D. Bordo and W. Roberds (eds.), The Origins, History, and Future of the Federal Reserve: A Return to Jekyll Island (New York: Cambridge University Press), 59–98.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • S. Bowles and H. Gintis (1993) ‘The Revenge of Homo Economicus: Contested Exchange and the Revival of Political Economy’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, VII, 83–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • P. C. Boyer and J. Ponce (2012) ‘Regulatory Capture and Banking Supervision Reform’, Journal of Financial Stability, VIII, 206–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • E. Brewer and J. Jagtiani (2013) ‘How Much Did Banks Pay to Become Too-Big-to-Fail and to Become Systemically Important?’, Journal of Financial Services Research, XLIII, 1–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • J. L. Broz (1997) The International Origins of the Federal Reserve System (Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • J. Bryant (1980) ‘A Model of Reserves, Bank Runs, and Deposit Insurance’, Journal of Banking and Finance, IV, 335–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • W. Buiter and A. Sibert (2007) ‘The Central Bank as the Market-Maker of Last Resort: From Lender of Last Resort to Market-Maker of Last Resort’ in A. Felton and C. Reinhart (eds), The First Global Financial Crisis of the 21st Century (London: CEPR), 171–178.

    Google Scholar 

  • C. W. Calomiris (1990) ‘Is Deposit Insurance Necessary? A Historical Perspective’, Journal of Economic History, L, 283–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • C. W. Calomiris, M. Flandreau, and L. Laeven (2016) ‘Political Foundations of the Lender of Last Resort: A Global Historical Narrative’, Journal of Financial Intermediation, XXVIII, 48–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • C. W. Calomiris and S. H. Haber (2014) Fragile by Design: The Political Origins of Banking Crises and Scarce Credit (Princeton: Princeton University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • C. W. Calomiris and C. M. Kahn (1991) ‘The Role of Demandable Debt in Structuring Optimal Banking Arrangements’, American Economic Review, LXXXI, 497–513.

    Google Scholar 

  • J. L. Carr and G. F. Mathewson (1988) ‘Unlimited Liability as a Barrier to Entry’, Journal of Political Economy, XCVI, 766–784.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • F. Castiglionesi and W. Wagner (2012) ‘Turning Bagehot on His Head: Lending at Penalty Rates when Banks Can Become Insolvent’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, XLIV, 201–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • S. Chapman (1984) The Rise of Merchant Banking (London: Allen & Unwin).

    Google Scholar 

  • M. Chinazzi and G. Fagiolo (2015), ‘Systemic Risk, Contagion, and Financial Networks: A Survey’ in I. Arribas-Fernández and E. Tortosa-Ausina (eds.), Banking Integration and Financial Crisis: Some Recent Developments (Bilbao: Fundación BBVA), 115–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • J. Clapham (1944) The Bank of England: A History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • P. L. Cottrell (2010) ‘“Conservative Abroad, Liberal at Home”: British Banking Regulation during the Nineteenth Century’ in S. Battilossi and J. Reis (eds.), State and Financial Systems in Europe and the USA: Historical Perspectives on Regulation and Supervision in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries (Farnham: Ashgate), 21–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • L. Dam and M. Koetter (2012) ‘Bank Bailouts and Moral Hazard: Evidence from Germany’, Review of Financial Studies, XXV, 2343–2380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • M. De Cecco (1974) Money and Empire: The International Gold Standard (Oxford: Blackwell).

    Google Scholar 

  • R. De Young and T. Rice (2004) ‘How Do Banks Make Money? The Fallacies of Fee Income’, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago: Economic Perspectives, XXVIII, 34–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • G. Debreu (1959) Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium (New York: Wiley).

    Google Scholar 

  • A. Demirgüç-Kunt, E. J. Kane, and L. Laeven (2015) ‘Deposit Insurance around the World: A Comprehensive Analysis and Database’, Journal of Financial Stability, XX, 155–183.

    Google Scholar 

  • M. Dewatripont and J. Tirole (1994) The Prudential Regulation of Banks (Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • D. W. Diamond (1984) ‘Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring’, Review of Economic Studies, LI, 393–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. W. Diamond and P. H. Dybvig (1983) ‘Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity’, Journal of Political Economy, XCI, 401–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. W. Diamond and R. G. Rajan (2001) ‘Liquidity Risk, Liquidity Creation, and Financial Fragility: A Theory of Banking’, Journal of Political Economy, CIX, 287–327.

    Google Scholar 

  • B. Eichengreen and M. Flandreau (2012) ‘The Federal Reserve, the Bank of England, and the Rise of the Dollar as an International Currency, 1914–1939’, Open Economies Review, XXIII, 57-87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • E. Farhi and J. Tirole (2012) ‘Collective Moral Hazard, Maturity Mismatch, and Systemic Bailouts’, American Economic Review, CII, 60–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • F. Ferrara (1871) ‘Gli antichi banchi di Venezia’, Nuova Antologia, XVI, 177–213 and 435–466.

    Google Scholar 

  • F. W. Fetter (1965) Development of British Monetary Orthodoxy, 1797–1875 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • M. Flandreau and S. Ugolini (2013) ‘Where It All Began: Lending of Last Resort and Bank of England Monitoring during the Overend-Gurney Panic of 1866’ in M. D. Bordo and W. Roberds (eds.), The Origins, History, and Future of the Federal Reserve: A Return to Jekyll Island (New York: Cambridge University Press), 113–161.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • M. Flandreau and S. Ugolini (2014) ‘The Crisis of 1866’ in N. Dimsdale and A. Hotson (eds.), British Financial Crises since 1825 (Oxford: Oxford University Press), 76–93.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • M. J. Flannery (1994) ‘Debt Maturity and the Deadweight Cost of Leverage: Optimally Financing Banking Firms’, American Economic Review, LXXXIV, 320–331.

    Google Scholar 

  • M. J. Flannery (1996) ‘Financial Crises, Payment System Problems, and Discount Window Lending’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, XXVIII, 804–824.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • J. H. Flores (2011) ‘Information Asymmetries and Conflict of Interests during the Baring Crisis, 1880–1890’, Financial History Review, XVIII, 191–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • X. Freixas, B. M. Parigi, and J.-C. Rochet (2004) ‘The Lender of Last Resort: A Twenty-First Century Approach’, Journal of the European Economic Association, II, 1085–1115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • X. Freixas and J.-C. Rochet (2008) Microeconomics of Banking (Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • X. Freixas and A. M. Santomero (2003) ‘An Overall Perspective on Banking Regulation’, working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • E. H. Freshfield (1938) Roman Law in the Later Roman Empire: Byzantine Guilds, Professional and Commercial: Ordinances of Leo VI, c. 895, from the Book of the Eparch (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • I. Goldstein and A. Pauzner (2005) ‘Demand-Deposit Contracts and the Probability of Bank Runs’, Journal of Finance, LX, 1293–1327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • M. S. Goodfriend (1991) ‘Money, Credit, Banking, and Payments System Policy’, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, LXXVII, 7–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • M. S. Goodfriend and R. G. King (1988) ‘Financial Deregulation, Monetary Policy, and Central Banking’, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, LXXIV, 3–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • C. A. E. Goodhart (1988) The Evolution of Central Banks (Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • C. A. E. Goodhart (1999) ‘Myths about the Lender of Last Resort’, International Finance, II, 339–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • C. A. E. Goodhart and D. Schoenmaker (1995) ‘Should the Functions of Monetary Policy and Banking Supervision Be Separated?’, Oxford Economic Papers, XLVII, 539–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G. Gorton (1988) ‘Banking Panics and Business Cycles’, Oxford Economic Papers, XL, 751–781.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G. Gorton (2012) Misunderstanding Financial Crises: Why We Don’t See Them Coming (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • G. Gorton and G. Ordoñez (2014) ‘How Central Banks End Crises’, working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • R. S. Grossman (2010) Unsettled Account: The Evolution of Banking in the Industrialized World since 1800 (Princeton: Princeton University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • R. S. Grossman and H. Rockoff (2016) ‘Fighting the Last War: Economists on the Lender of Last Resort’ in M. D. Bordo, Ø. Eitrheim, M. Flandreau, and J. F. Qvigstad (eds.), Central Banks at a Crossroads: What Can We Learn from History? (New York: Cambridge University Press), 231–279.

    Google Scholar 

  • F. Grubb (2003) ‘Creating the U.S. Dollar Currency Union, 1748–1811: A Quest for Monetary Stability or a Usurpation of State Sovereignty for Personal Gain?’, American Economic Review, XCIII, 1778–1798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • T. Hankey (1867) The Principles of Banking, Its Utility and Economy (London: Effingham Wilson).

    Google Scholar 

  • P.-C. Hautcoeur, A. Riva, and E. N. White (2014) ‘Floating a “Lifeboat”: The Banque de France and the Crisis of 1889’, Journal of Monetary Economics, LXV, 104–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • R. G. Hawtrey (1932) The Art of Central Banking (London: Longmans, Green & Co).

    Google Scholar 

  • T. L. Hogan, L. Le, and A. W. Salter (2015) ‘Ben Bernanke and Bagehot’s Rules’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, XLVII, 333–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • B. Holmström and J. Tirole (1997) ‘Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and the Real Sector’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXII, 663–691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • T. M. Humphrey (2010) ‘Lender of Last Resort: What It Is, Whence It Came, and Why the Fed Isn’t It’, Cato Journal, XXX, 333–364.

    Google Scholar 

  • T. M. Humphrey and R. E. Keleher (1984) ‘The Lender of Last Resort: A Historical Perspective’, Cato Journal, IV, 275–318.

    Google Scholar 

  • A.-C. Hüser (2015) ‘Too Interconnected to Fail: A Survey of the Interbank Networks Literature’, working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • C. J. Jacklin (1987) ‘Demand Deposits, Trading Restrictions, and Risk Sharing’ in E. C. Prescott and N. Wallace (eds.), Contractual Arrangements for Intertemporal Trade (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press), 26–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • C. Jobst and H. Kernbauer (2016) The Quest for Stable Money: Central Banking in Austria, 1816–2016 (Frankfurt am Main: Campus).

    Google Scholar 

  • C. Jobst and S. Ugolini (2016) ‘The Coevolution of Money Markets and Monetary Policy, 1815–2008’ in M. D. Bordo, Ø. Eitrheim, M. Flandreau, and J. F. Qvigstad (eds.), Central Banks at a Crossroads: What Can We Learn from History? (New York: Cambridge University Press), 145–194.

    Google Scholar 

  • C. M. Kahn and W. Roberds (2002) ‘The Economics of Payment Finality’, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review, LXXXVII, 1–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • C. M. Kahn and J. A. C. Santos (2005) ‘Allocating Bank Regulatory Powers: Lender of Last Resort, Deposit Insurance and Supervision’, European Economic Review, XLIX, 2107–2136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • E. J. Kane (1989) The S & L Insurance Mess: How Did It Happen? (Washington, DC: Urban Institute Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • T. Keister (2016) ‘Bailouts and Financial Fragility’, Review of Economic Studies, LXXXIII, 704–736.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • C. P. Kindleberger (1978) Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises (Basingstoke: Macmillan).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • W. T. C. King (1936) History of the London Discount Market (London: Routledge).

    Google Scholar 

  • L. Laeven (2002) ‘International Evidence on the Value of Deposit Insurance’, Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, XLII, 721–732.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. Laidler (2004) ‘Central Banks as Lenders of Last Resort: Trendy or Passé?’, working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • E. Lattes (1869) La libertà delle banche a Venezia dal secolo XIII al XVII (Milan: Valentiner & Mues).

    Google Scholar 

  • J. M. Leonard (1940) ‘Superadded Liability of Bank Stockholders’, Temple University Law Quarterly, XIV, 522–525.

    Google Scholar 

  • M. C. Lovell (1957) ‘The Role of the Bank of England as Lender of Last Resort in the Crises of the Eighteenth Century’, Explorations in Entrepreneurial History, X, 8–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • J. R. Macey and G. P. Miller (1992) ‘Double Liability of Bank Shareholders: History and Implications’, Wake Forest Law Review, XXVII, 31–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • A. Martin (2006) ‘Liquidity Provision vs. Deposit Insurance: Preventing Bank Panics without Moral Hazard’, Economic Theory, XXVIII, 197–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • A. Martin (2009) ‘Reconciling Bagehot and the Fed’s Response to September 11’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, XLI, 397–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • D. Masciandaro and M. Quintyn (2016) ‘The Governance of Financial Supervision: Recent Developments’, Journal of Economic Surveys, XXX, 982–1006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • R. I. McKinnon (1973) Money and Capital in Economic Development (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution).

    Google Scholar 

  • P. Mehrling (2011) The New Lombard Street: How the Fed Became the Dealer of Last Resort (Princeton: Princeton University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • R. C. Merton (1977) ‘An Analytic Derivation of the Cost of Deposit Insurance and Loan Guarantees: An Application of Modern Option Pricing Theory’, Journal of Banking and Finance, I, 3–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • G. Moore (1999) ‘Solutions to the Moral Hazard Problem Arising from the Lender-of-Last-Resort Facility’, Journal of Economic Surveys, XIII, 443–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • S. Morris and H. S. Shin (2016) ‘Illiquidity Component of Credit Risk’, International Economic Review, LVII, 1135–1148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • R. C. Mueller (1997), The Venetian Money Market: Banks, Panics, and the Public Debt, 1200–1500 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • P. Pierucci (1991) ‘La Zecca ragusea come banca pubblica nella seconda metà del XVIII secolo: il ruolo economico’ in Banchi pubblici, banchi privati e monti di pietà nell’Europa preindustriale (Genoa: Società Ligure di Storia Patria), 925–940.

    Google Scholar 

  • A. Postlewaite and X. Vives (1987) ‘Bank Runs as an Equilibrium Phenomenon’, Journal of Political Economy, XCV, 485–491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • L. S. Pressnell (1956) Country Banking in the Industrial Revolution (Oxford: Clarendon Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • L. S. Pressnell (1968) ‘Gold Reserves, Banking Reserves, and the Baring Crisis of 1890’ in C. R. Whittlesey and J. S. G. Wilson (eds.), Essays in Money and Banking in Honour of R. S. Sayers (Oxford: Clarendon Press), 167–228.

    Google Scholar 

  • S. Quinn and W. Roberds (2015) ‘Responding to a Shadow Banking Crisis: The Lessons of 1763’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, XLVII, 1149–1176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • R. Repullo (2000) ‘Who Should Act as Lender of Last Resort? An Incomplete Contracts Model’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, XXXII, 580–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • R. Repullo (2005) ‘Liquidity, Risk Taking, and the Lender of Last Resort’, International Journal of Central Banking, I, 47–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • R. D. Richards (1929) The Early History of Banking in England (London: King).

    Google Scholar 

  • R. Roberts (2013) Saving the City: The Great Financial Crisis of 1914 (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • J.-C. Rochet and X. Vives (2004) ‘Coordination Failures and the Lender of Last Resort: Was Bagehot Right After All?’, Journal of the European Economic Association, II, 1116–1147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • H. Rockoff (1991) ‘Lessons from the American Experience with Free Banking’ in F. Capie and G. E. Wood (eds.), Unregulated Banking: Chaos or Order? (Basingstoke: Macmillan), 73–109.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • G. Roulleau (1914) Les règlements par effets de commerce en France et à l’étranger (Paris: Dubreuil-Frèrebeau).

    Google Scholar 

  • J. A. C. Santos (2006) ‘Insuring Banks against Liquidity Shocks: The Role of Deposit Insurance and Lending of Last Resort’, Journal of Economic Surveys, XX, 459–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • I. Schnabel and H. S. Shin (2004) ‘Liquidity and Contagion: The Crisis of 1763’, Journal of the European Economic Association, II, 929–968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • C. Sleet and B. D. Smith (2000) ‘Deposit Insurance and Lender-of-Last-Resort Functions’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, XXXII, 518–575.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • R. Solow (1982) ‘On the Lender of Last Resort’ in C. P. Kindleberger and J. Laffargue (eds), Financial Crises: Theory, History and Policy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), 237–248.

    Google Scholar 

  • F. M. Tamagna (1963) ‘Processes and Instruments of Monetary Policy: A Comparative Analysis’ in Monetary Management: Prepared for the Commission on Money and Credit (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall), 1–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • E. R. Taus (1943) Central Banking Functions of the United States Treasury, 1789–1941 (New York: Columbia University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • H. Thornton (1802) An Enquiry into the Nature and Effects of the Paper Credit of Great Britain (London: Hatchard).

    Google Scholar 

  • R. H. Timberlake (1993) Monetary Policy in the United States: An Intellectual and Institutional History (Chicago and London: Chicago University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • G. Toniolo and E. N. White (2016) ‘The Evolution of the Financial Stability Mandate: From Its Origins to the Present Day’ in M. D. Bordo, Ø. Eitrheim, M. Flandreau, and J. F. Qvigstad (eds.), Central Banks at a Crossroads: What Can We Learn from History? (New York: Cambridge University Press), 424–492.

    Google Scholar 

  • J. D. Turner (2014) Banking in Crisis: The Rise and Fall of British Banking Stability, 1800 to the Present (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • S. Ugolini (2014) ‘Comment on: “Floating a “Lifeboat”: The Banque de France and the Crisis of 1889” by P. C. Hautcoeur, A. Riva, and E. N. White’, Journal of Monetary Economics, LXV, 120–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • S. Ugolini (2016a) ‘Liquidity Management and Central Bank Strength: Bank of England Operations Reloaded, 1889–1910’, Norges Bank Working Paper, 10/2016.

    Google Scholar 

  • R. Uittenbogaard (2009) ‘Lending by the Bank of Amsterdam (1609–1802)’ in M. Van Nieuwkerk (ed.), The Bank of Amsterdam: On the Origins of Central Banking (Arnhem: Sonsbeek), 120–131.

    Google Scholar 

  • J. Van Fenstermaker (1965) ‘The Statistics of American Commercial Banking, 1782–1818’, Journal of Economic History, XXV, 400–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • P. M. Warburg (1910) The Discount System in Europe (Washington, DC: National Monetary Commission).

    Google Scholar 

  • R. B. Westerfield (1932) ‘Collateral to Discounts at the Federal Reserve Banks’, American Economic Review, XXII, 34–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • E. N. White (1983) The Regulation and Reform of the American Banking System, 1900–1929 (Princeton: Princeton University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • E. Wood (1939) English Theories of Central Banking Control, 1819–1858 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Ugolini, S. (2017). Lending of Last Resort and Supervision. In: The Evolution of Central Banking: Theory and History. Palgrave Studies in Economic History. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-48525-0_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-48525-0_3

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-137-48524-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-137-48525-0

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics