Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Palgrave Studies in Economic History ((PEHS))

  • 1416 Accesses

Abstract

Today, central banks are independent agencies which make part of the public sector. This particular institutional arrangement is recent, and potentially fragile: other equilibria are arguably possible, ranging from complete “internalization” by the government to complete “externalization” to the private sector. In order to understand the determinants of changes in such institutional equilibria, it is appropriate to adopt a functional approach. This means focusing not on the evolution of central banks as organizations, but on the evolution of the provision of central banking functions. Central banking functions arguably consist of two microeconomic functions aimed at fostering financial stability (viz., the management of the payment system and banking regulation), as well as two macroeconomic functions aimed at fostering monetary stability (viz., money creation and monetary policy).

Whoever wants to come to a good and sound conclusion must not make up his mind before paying attention to all arguments, or (as the say goes) “bring the verdict to Senate from home”; rather, while leaving his judgment pending and not leaning more in one direction than in the other, he must listen impartially to everything that is being said, scrutinize every opinion, and – dispassionately and unbiasedly – invoke and embrace God’s enlightenment.

Tommaso Contarini , Speech to the Venetian Senate in Support of the Creation of a Public Bank, 28 December 1584 (quoted in Lattes (1869, p. 118), my translation).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See, for example, Siklos (2002).

  2. 2.

    See, for example, Bindseil (2004).

  3. 3.

    Borio (2014, p. 191).

  4. 4.

    Davies and Green (2010).

  5. 5.

    Qvigstad (2016, pp. 124–155).

  6. 6.

    Goodhart (1988). The first edition of the book was published in 1985.

  7. 7.

    Hayek (1978).

  8. 8.

    Smith (1990). This book consists of Vera Smith ’s doctoral dissertation (supervised by Hayek ); originally published in 1936, it only started to gain popularity after the author’s death in 1976.

  9. 9.

    White (1989). This volume collects the essays the author had been publishing in the preceding years.

  10. 10.

    Timberlake (1984).

  11. 11.

    In a nutshell: “The crucial feature necessary to allow a Central Bank to carry out, in full, its various functions , e.g., of maintaining financial discipline, providing support at times of crisis, is that it should become above the competitive battle, a noncompetitive , non-profit-maximizing body. This was not generally recognized at the outset. In the first half of the nineteenth century, the key feature of a Central Bank was seen to reside in its relationship with government and its privileged position as (monopolistic ) note issuer: but in its banking function, it was often widely considered that it was, and should act as, just one competitive bank among many. This concept of a Central Bank’s role was codified in the 1844 Bank of England Act . But this was, as argued above, an incorrect, indeed faulty, concept, and, I would argue, true Central Banking did not develop until the need for the Central Banks to be noncompetitive had become realized and established. This metamorphosis occurred slowly and by trial, error, and debate in England in the last half of the nineteenth century, in some large part following the prompting of Bagehot . It was a difficult transition […]”: Goodhart (1988, pp. 45–46, my emphasis).

  12. 12.

    For a discussion of Goodhart ’s contribution to the literature on the evolution of central banks, see Uittenbogaard (2015, pp. 11–29).

  13. 13.

    Goodhart had been with the Bank of England from 1968 to 1985 and has remained a prominent figure in central banking circles since: Goodhart (1988, pp. vii–viii).

  14. 14.

    See esp. the “universal” survey of central bank history provided by Capie et al. (1994), which remains a benchmark reference in the literature.

  15. 15.

    Clapham (1944).

  16. 16.

    Morgan (1943).

  17. 17.

    King (1936).

  18. 18.

    Hawtrey (1932, 1938).

  19. 19.

    Gregory (1929).

  20. 20.

    Bagehot (1873).

  21. 21.

    Goodhart (1988, p. 46).

  22. 22.

    Fetter (1965).

  23. 23.

    Wood (1939).

  24. 24.

    Bagehot (1867).

  25. 25.

    Bagehot (1872).

  26. 26.

    Hodgson (2004).

  27. 27.

    Cowles (1937). On the personal links between Bagehot and Darwin , also see Flandreau (2016).

  28. 28.

    To be precise, Charles Darwin did not put forward himself this idea, which was rather coined in the social sciences by Herbert Spencer : Hudson (2000, p. 535).

  29. 29.

    The “survivor bias ” is the error of taking into account only continued processes while ignoring discontinued ones.

  30. 30.

    “We are aware that blind forces are not at work here [in the evolution of central banking], but human beings grappling for solutions to problems they perhaps do not fully understand. Nor do we necessarily think that all hillclimbing algorithms find the global optimum: where one arrives often depends on initial conditions and on the path followed. […] Central banking involves a sort of alchemy, and what we see in our history is a search for the right formula. We do not conclude that it has been found; if anything, we are left with a sense that the search continues”: Roberds and Velde (2016, pp. 19–20).

  31. 31.

    Giannini (2011). The Italian version of the book had been published posthumously in 2004.

  32. 32.

    Giannini was with the Banca d’Italia from 1983 to 2003, when he passed away: Giannini (2011, pp. viii–ix).

  33. 33.

    In a nutshell: “With the industrial revolution and virtually contemporaneous development of the representative state a structural split occurred. On the one side, as the economic circuit became increasingly complex it fuelled the social incentive to develop more flexible payment procedures. On the other side, under the new political and institutional framework monetary institutions could, for the first time, develop outside the control of the prince. Any attempt to move beyond commodity money , even in its most advanced form of coinage , must entail an intermingling of money circuit and credit circuit. […] The intermingling of money and credit circuit thus set in motion a long and somewhat tortuous process of institutional adaptation centred around the figure of the central bank”: Giannini (2011, pp. xxvi–xxvii).

  34. 34.

    The word “institutional” is used in economics with plenty of different meanings. Here I follow Merton and Bodie (1995) and use it merely as opposed to the word “functional”—with no other implication.

  35. 35.

    Capie et al. (1994, p. 5).

  36. 36.

    See, for example, Joplin (1837, pp. 22 and 38).

  37. 37.

    See, for example, Gilbart (1865, pp. 557–570). It is interesting to notice that even Bagehot makes use of the word “central bank” only twice in Lombard Street—and in both cases, with reference to the headquarters of a multi-branched bank, not to a bank of issue (Bagehot 1873, pp. 57 and 88–89).

  38. 38.

    This is encapsulated by Grossman ’s (2010, pp. 42–44) claim that before the 1870s central banks did not exist as “there was no accepted concept of a central bank,” and that only thanks to Bagehot “the modern concept of central bank began to gain widespread acceptance.” This idea is extensively enunciated by Capie (2002). Also see Siklos (2002, p. 10) and Davies and Green (2010, p. 11).

  39. 39.

    Bignon et al. (2012).

  40. 40.

    See Sect. 1.1.3.

  41. 41.

    See, for example, Kindleberger (1991); Schnabel and Shin (2006); Quinn and Roberds (2007). As we shall see, however, if we followed this definition, primacy should probably be ascribed to Venice ’s Banco del Giro : see Sect. 5.2.1.

  42. 42.

    See, for example, the eighteenth-century debate between supporters of banks of issue and supporters of giro banks : Gillard (2004).

  43. 43.

    This concerns the origin of the word “bank” in English. According to the standard interpretation, “bank” would derive from the Italian equivalent for “bench”, meaning the counter over which medieval moneychangers used to deal their transactions: this would appear consistent with the idea that central banks were created to fix problems with the payment system . Such an interpretation, however, has been questioned by some, according to whom “bank” would rather derive from the Germanic equivalent for “cliff”, meaning the amount (the joint stock) of public debt handled by the institution—which would correspond to the Italian word “monte” rather than “banco”: this would appear consistent with the idea that central banks were created to monetize government deficits : Conant (1909, pp. 8–9).

  44. 44.

    For a discussion on the application of the functional approach to the analysis of financial systems, see Merton and Bodie (1995). The functionalist approach to social systems has been particularly promoted by sociologist Robert K. Merton ; it has been extended to financial systems by economist Robert C. Merton , son of the former.

  45. 45.

    Central Bank Governance Group (2009).

  46. 46.

    See Oliver Sprague ’s chapter on central banks in the third (accrued) edition of Charles Dunbar ’s Theory and History of Banking: Dunbar (1917, pp. iii and 85–86).

  47. 47.

    A partial survey of the literature can be found in Singleton (2011, pp. 4–5).

  48. 48.

    For a critical discussion on the epistemological relevance of “Occam’s razor ”, see, for example, Walsh (1979).

  49. 49.

    For instance, Singleton (2011, pp. 5–11) finally proposes a list of nine functions (plus a tenth category of “other functions”). Some of these, however, are tailored to some peculiar twentieth-century condition that did not exist in other settings: this is the case of function number 9 (“participating in cooperative international agreements”), which was not an issue before 1914: Flandreau (1997). Some others can reasonably be merged: this is the case of function numbers 2 (“implementing monetary policy ”) and 6 (“managing foreign reserves and exchange rate targets”), which can be seen as two aspects of the same function. As Singleton (2011, pp. 10–11) himself does recognize, redundancy gives scope for inconclusive discussions about which functions are core and which ones are peripheral.

  50. 50.

    See, for example, Issing (2003).

  51. 51.

    Here I refer particularly (although not exclusively) to the list of central banking functions that the Federal Reserve understood (as of 1983) to have been entrusted by lawmakers since its foundation: “The Congress has over the last 70 years authorized the Federal Reserve (a) to be a major participant in the nation’s payments mechanism , (b) to lend at the discount window as the ultimate source of liquidity for the economy, and (c) to regulate and supervise key sectors of the financial markets, both domestic and international. These functions are in addition to, and largely predate, the more purely “monetary” functions of engaging in open market and foreign exchange operations, and setting reserve requirements ; historically, in fact, the “monetary” functions were largely grafted on the “supervisory” functions, not the reverse”: Volcker (1984, p. 548).

  52. 52.

    Botha (1975). Here I refer to the second revised edition: De Kock (1946).

  53. 53.

    Botha (1975).

  54. 54.

    Capie et al. (1994, p. 21).

  55. 55.

    See esp. Singleton (2011).

Bibliography

  • W. Bagehot (1867) The English Constitution (London: Clapman & Hall).

    Google Scholar 

  • W. Bagehot (1872) Physics and Politics: Thoughts on the Application of the Principles of “Natural Selection” and “Inheritance” to Political Society (London: King).

    Google Scholar 

  • W. Bagehot (1873) Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market (London: King).

    Google Scholar 

  • V. Bignon, M. Flandreau, and S. Ugolini (2012) ‘Bagehot for Beginners: The Making of Lending-of-Last-Resort Operations in the Mid-19th Century’, Economic History Review, LXV, 580–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • U. Bindseil (2004) Monetary Policy Implementation: Theory, Past, Present (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • C. Borio (2014) ‘Central Banking Post-crisis: What Compass for Uncharted Waters?’ in C. A. E. Goodhart, D. Gabor, J. Vestergaard, and I. Ertürk (eds.), Central Banking at a Crossroads: Europe and Beyond (London: Anthem Press), 191–216.

    Google Scholar 

  • D. J. J. Botha (1975) ‘Dr. M. H. de Kock on Central Banking’, South African Journal of Economics, XLIII, 35–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • F. Capie (2002) ‘The Emergence of the Bank of England as a Mature Central Bank’ in D. Winch and P. K. O’Brien (eds.), The Political Economy of British Historical Experience (Oxford: Oxford University Press), 295–318.

    Google Scholar 

  • F. Capie, C. A. E. Goodhart, and N. Schnadt (1994) ‘The Development of Central Banking’ in F. Capie, C. A. E. Goodhart, S. Fischer, and N. Schnadt (eds.), The Future of Central Banking: The Tercentenary Symposium of the Bank of England (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), 1–231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Central Bank Governance Group (2009) ‘Issues in the Governance of Central Banks’, Bank for International Settlements Reports.

    Google Scholar 

  • J. Clapham (1944) The Bank of England: A History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • C. A. Conant (1909) A History of Modern Banks of Issue (London: Putnam).

    Google Scholar 

  • T. Cowles (1937) ‘Malthus, Darwin, and Bagehot: A Study in the Transference of a Concept’, Isis, XXVI, 341–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • H. Davies and D. Green (2010) Banking on the Future: The Fall and Rise of Central Banking (Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • M. H. De Kock (1946) Central Banking (New York and Toronto: Staples Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • C. F. Dunbar (1917) The Theory and History of Banking (New York and London: Putnam).

    Google Scholar 

  • F. W. Fetter (1965) Development of British Monetary Orthodoxy, 1797–1875 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • M. Flandreau (1997) ‘Central Bank Cooperation in Historical Perspective: A Sceptical View’, Economic History Review, L, 735–763.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • M. Flandreau (2016) Anthropologists in the Stock Exchange: A Financial History of Victorian Science (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • C. Giannini (2011) The Age of Central Banks (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • J. W. Gilbart (1865) The Logic of Banking: A Familiar Exposition of the Principles of Reasoning, and Their Application to the Art and the Science of Banking (London: Bell & Daldy).

    Google Scholar 

  • L. Gillard (2004) La banque d’Amsterdam et le florin européen au temps de la République néerlandaise (1610–1820) (Paris: EHESS).

    Google Scholar 

  • C. A. E. Goodhart (1988) The Evolution of Central Banks (Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • T. E. Gregory (1929) Select Statutes, Documents and Reports Relating to British Banking, 1832–1928 (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • R. S. Grossman (2010) Unsettled Account: The Evolution of Banking in the Industrialized World since 1800 (Princeton: Princeton University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • R. G. Hawtrey (1932) The Art of Central Banking (London: Longmans, Green & Co).

    Google Scholar 

  • R. G. Hawtrey (1938) A Century of Bank Rate (London: Longmans, Green & Co).

    Google Scholar 

  • F. A. Hayek (1978) Denationalisation of Money: The Argument Refined (London: Institute of Economic Affairs).

    Google Scholar 

  • G. M. Hodgson (2004) ‘Social Darwinism in Anglophone Academic Journals: A Contribution to the History of the Term’, Journal of Historical Sociology, XVII, 428–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • C. G. Hudson (2000) ‘From Social Darwinism to Self-Organization: Implications for Social Change Theory’, Social Service Review, LXXIV, 533–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O. Issing (2003) ‘Monetary and Financial Stability: Is There a Trade-Off?’ in Monetary and Economic Department (ed.), Monetary Stability, Financial Stability and the Business Cycle: Five Views (Basel: Bank for International Settlements), 16–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • T. Joplin (1837) An Examination of the Report of the Joint Stock Committee (London: Ridgway & Sons).

    Google Scholar 

  • C. P. Kindleberger (1991) ‘Currency Debasement in the Early Seventeenth Century and the Establishment of Deposit Banks in Central Europe’ in Banchi pubblici, banchi privati e monti di pietà nell’Europa preindustriale (Genoa: Società Ligure di Storia Patria), 35–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • W. T. C. King (1936) History of the London Discount Market (London: Routledge).

    Google Scholar 

  • E. Lattes (1869) La libertà delle banche a Venezia dal secolo XIII al XVII (Milan: Valentiner & Mues).

    Google Scholar 

  • R. C. Merton and Z. Bodie (1995) ‘A Conceptual Framework for Analyzing the Financial Environment’ in The Global Financial System: A Functional Perspective (Boston: Harvard Business School Press), 3–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • E. V. Morgan (1943) The Theory and Practice of Central Banking, 1797–1913 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • S. Quinn and W. Roberds (2007) ‘The Bank of Amsterdam and the Leap to Central Bank Money’, American Economic Review, XCVII, 262–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • J. F. Qvigstad (2016) On Central Banking (New York: Cambridge University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • W. Roberds and F. R. Velde (2016) ‘The Descent of Central Banks (1400–1815)’ in M. D. Bordo, Ø. Eitrheim, M. Flandreau, and J. F. Qvigstad (eds.), Central Banks at a Crossroads: What Can We Learn from History? (New York: Cambridge University Press), 18–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • I. Schnabel and H. S. Shin (2006) ‘The “Kipper- und Wipperzeit” and the Foundation of Public Deposit Banks’, working paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • P. L. Siklos (2002) The Changing Face of Central Banking: Evolutionary Trends since World War II (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • J. Singleton (2011) Central Banking in the Twentieth Century (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • V. C. Smith (1990) The Rationale of Central Banking and the Free Banking Alternative (Indianapolis: Liberty Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • R. H. Timberlake (1984) ‘The Central Banking Role of Clearinghouse Associations’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, XVI, 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • R. Uittenbogaard (2015) Evolution of Central Banking? De Nederlandsche Bank, 1814–1852 (Cham: Springer).

    Google Scholar 

  • P. A. Volcker (1984) ‘The Federal Reserve Position on Restructuring of Financial Regulation Responsibilities’, Federal Reserve Bulletin, LXX, 547–557.

    Google Scholar 

  • D. Walsh (1979) ‘Occam’s Razor: A Principle of Intellectual Elegance’, American Philosophical Quarterly, XVI, 241–244.

    Google Scholar 

  • L. H. White (1989) Competition and Currency: Essays on Free Banking and Money (New York and London: New York University Press).

    Google Scholar 

  • E. Wood (1939) English Theories of Central Banking Control, 1819–1858 (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Ugolini, S. (2017). Introduction. In: The Evolution of Central Banking: Theory and History. Palgrave Studies in Economic History. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-48525-0_1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-48525-0_1

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-137-48524-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-137-48525-0

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics