Skip to main content

Classical Political Economy

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Abstract

This chapter aims to outline the worldview, analytical principles and modern implications of Classical Political Economy (CPE). It presents CPE as a study of the key features of industrial economies, emphasizing its approach to aggregation and structural change. The first part of the chapter focusses on the analytical coordinates of the two main Classical Political Economists—Adam Smith and David Ricardo—in view of extracting their contribution to understanding industrial economies. The second part uses a modern theory inspired by the Classics to illustrate how CPE can be generalized to understand production, growth and distribution in modern industrial economies. The chapter concludes by highlighting that the legacy of CPE includes analytical tools to address problems of aggregation in society that go beyond the specific aims for which they were developed (i.e. assigning weights to different commodities within the net product).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   349.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   449.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    There are divergent interpretations as to the extent to which Classical theories explicitly consider interdependencies. For example, whilst Sraffa (1960) interprets Ricardo’s theory in terms of interdependencies between industries, Hicks (1985) believes that Ricardo had in mind vertically integrated sectors, that is the set of all activities necessary for the production of final goods, irrespective of the industry in which they are performed. As I discuss later in this essay, it is possible to switch from one to the other of the above representations (Pasinetti 1973). Hence, I will only discuss whether the Classics adopted one or the other representation when doing so is directly relevant for the analysis at hand.

  2. 2.

    Whilst these periods are typically referred to as “years”, they need not correspond to calendar years.

  3. 3.

    See Landesmann (2018‚ this Handbook) for an analysis of structural change in CPE and its ramifications in economic theory.

  4. 4.

    Although the interpretation of Smith’s distinction between productive and unproductive labour is a contentious one, for the purposes of this essay I will take the distinction to be that productive workers are those whose work reintegrates wage (capital advances) and generates a surplus: “There is one sort of labour which adds to the value of the subject upon which it is bestowed: there is another which has no such effect. The former, as it produces a value, may be called productive; the latter, unproductive labour” (WN, p. 330).

  5. 5.

    It must, however, be said that Smith, like many Enlightenment thinkers, is also interested in markets for their “civilizing” effects (see Hirschman 1982). And although it might be interesting to consider whether such effects should be interpreted as pertaining to the sphere of exchange alone, or more generally to the interaction between the sphere of exchange and that of production (especially the deepening of the division of labour), these issues are beyond the scope of this chapter and I shall not pursue them further.

  6. 6.

    A different interpretive line attributes to Smith a treatment of value and distribution based on the “adding up” theory of natural price (Dobb 1973; see also Sraffa 1951, p. xxxv). Smith’s approach has been a matter of controversy since shortly after his formulation (e.g. Storch 1823 [1st edn. 1815]; Ziber 1871; see Scazzieri 1987). On the problem of value in CPE and its connection with the dynamics of production, see also Sinha (2018‚ this Handbook).

  7. 7.

    Pasinetti (1981, p. 132) shows that, under certain conditions, a pure labour theory of value can be shown to hold even in a capital-using economy.

References

  • Arrow, K.J., and D.A. Starrett. 1973. Cost- and Demand-Theoretical Approaches to the Theory of Price Determination. In Carl Menger and the Austrian School of Economics, ed. J.R. Hicks and W. Weber, 129–148. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardinale, I. 2017. Sectoral Interests and ‘Systemic’ Interest: Towards a Structural Political Economy of the Eurozone. In The Political Economy of the Eurozone, ed. I. Cardinale, D. Coffman, and R. Scazzieri, 216–237. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Cardinale, I. 2018. Structural Political Economy. In The Palgrave Handbook of Political Economy, ed. I. Cardinale and R. Scazzieri. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardinale, I., and R. Scazzieri. 2018. Political Economy as Theory of Society. In The Palgrave Handbook of Political Economy, ed. I. Cardinale and R. Scazzieri. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, A.K. 1985. Epochs of Economic Theory. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dobb, M. 1973. Theories of Value and Distribution Since Adam Smith. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Garegnani, P. 1960. Il capitale nelle teorie della distribuzione. Milan: Giuffrè.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. 1975. The Scope and Status of Welfare Economics. Oxford Economic Papers (New Series), 27 (3): 307–326.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. 1976. ‘Revolutions’ in Economics. In Method and Appraisal in Economics, ed. S. Latsis, 207–218. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J.R. 1985. Sraffa and Ricardo: A Critical View. In The Legacy of Ricardo, ed. G. Caravale, 305–319. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A.O. 1982. Rival Interpretation of Market Society: Civilizing, Destructive, or Feeble? Journal of Economic Literature 20 (4): 1463–1484.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landesmann, M.A. 2018. Political Economy of Structural Change. In The Palgrave Handbook of Political Economy, ed. I. Cardinale and R. Scazzieri. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leontief, W. 1941. The Structure of American Economy, 1919–29. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malthus, T.R. 1815. An Inquiry into the Nature and Progress of Rent, and the Principles by Which It Is Regulated. London: Murray.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L.L. 1960. A Mathematical Formulation of the Ricardian System. The Review of Economic Studies 27 (2): 78–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L.L. 1973. The Notion of Vertical Integration in Economic Analysis. Metroeconomica 25 (1): 1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L.L. 1981. Structural Change and Economic Growth: A Theoretical Essay on the Dynamics of the Wealth of Nations. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L.L. 1986. Theory of Value—A Source of Alternative Paradigms in Economic Analysis. In Foundations of Economics: Structure of Inquiry and Economic Theory, ed. Mauro Baranzini and Roberto Scazzieri, 409–431. Oxford and New York: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L.L. 1988. Growing Subsystems Vertically Hyper-Integrated Sectors and the Labour Theory of Value. Cambridge Journal of Economics 12: 125–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L.L. 1993. Structural Economic Dynamics: A Theory of the Economic Consequences of Human Learning. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L.L. 2012. Growth and Structural Change: Perspectives for the Future. In Structural Dynamics and Economic Growth, ed. R. Arena and P.L. Porta, 276–282. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L.L. 2015. On the Origin of the Theory of Rent in Economics. In Resources, Production and Structural Dynamics, ed. M.L. Baranzini, C. Rotondi, and R. Scazzieri, 35–52. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Quadrio Curzio, A. 1967. Rendita e distribuzione in un modello economico plurisettoriale. Milan: Giuffré.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quadrio Curzio, A. 1986. Technological Scarcity: An Essay on Production and Structural Change. In Foundations of Economics: Structure of Inquiry and Economic Theory, ed. Mauro Baranzini and Roberto Scazzieri, 311–338. Oxford and New York: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quadrio Curzio, A., and F. Pellizzari. 2018. Political Economy of Resources, Technologies and Rent. In The Palgrave Handbook of Political Economy, ed. I. Cardinale and R. Scazzieri. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo, D. 1951 [1st edn. 1817]. On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, vol. I of The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, ed. P. Sraffa with the collaboration of M.H. Dobb. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scazzieri, R. 1987. Ziber on Ricardo. Contributions to Political Economy 6: 25–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scazzieri, R. 2018. Political Economy of Economic Theory. In The Palgrave Handbook of Political Economy, ed. I. Cardinale and R. Scazzieri. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinha, A. 2018. Political Economy of Economic Value. In The Palgrave Handbook of Political Economy, ed. I. Cardinale and R. Scazzieri. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. 1976 [1st edn. 1776]. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, ed. W.B. Todd, vol. II of The Glasgow Edition of the Works and Correspondence of Adam Smith, ed. R.H. Campbell and A.S. Skinner. Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. 1951. Introduction. In On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, vol. I of The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, ed. P. Sraffa with the collaboration of M.H. Dobb (xiii–lxii). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. 1960. Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities: Prelude to a Critique of Economic Theory. Cambridge: University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storch, H. 1823 [1st edn. 1815]. Cours d’économie politique. Paris: Aillaud.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J. 1945–46. A Model of General Economic Equilibrium. The Review of Economic Studies 13 (1): 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziber, N.I. 1871. Teoriia Tsennosti i Kapitala D. Rikardo, v sviazh s pozdnieishimi dopolneniiami i taz’iasneniiami [Ricardo’s Theory of Value and Capital, in Relation to the Latest Additions and Explanations]. Universitetskiia Izviestiia (Kiev), Nos. 1–2 and 4–11.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ivano Cardinale .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Cardinale, I. (2018). Classical Political Economy. In: Cardinale, I., Scazzieri, R. (eds) The Palgrave Handbook of Political Economy. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-44254-3_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-44254-3_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-137-44253-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-137-44254-3

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics