Skip to main content

Charles Babbage (1791–1871)

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover The Palgrave Companion to Cambridge Economics

Abstract

Charles Babbage was ahead of his time not only in inventing the Analytical Engine but also because of many of his contributions to economics. He is best known in economics for the so-called Babbage Principle, which provides an explanation for the emergence of large-scale production units characterised by a hierarchy of skills and a corresponding hierarchy of wages. The full importance of other aspects of Babbage’s contributions covering search and other transactions costs, the role of reputation and middlemen, and the relationship between these and forms of industrial organisation came to be appreciated only in the twentieth century. Babbage’s theory of monopoly, according to which monopoly is always temporary and its sustainability requires the charging of the competitive price, also has a distinctly modern ring. As might be expected, Babbage also contributed to our understanding of technological progress. His successes in political economy were not the result of his mathematical prowess but rather the product of his deep knowledge of the manufacturing system.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 189.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The truth of synthetic propositions is determined by how their meaning relates to the world, whereas analytic propositions are true by virtue of their meaning.

  2. 2.

    Richard Jones, who read the draft manuscript, thought it ‘a strange collection of facts taken from his [Babbage’s] commonplace book’ (Schaffer 2003: 284–285). McCulloch’s (1833) review in the Edinburgh Review can be best described as lukewarm.

  3. 3.

    The first version entitled ‘An Essay on the General Principles which Regulate the Application of Machinery to Manufactures and the Mechanical Arts’ was published in 1827 and did not include any material on the domestic and political economy of manufactures. An expanded version, including the economic material, was published in 1829 (see Babbage 1829).

  4. 4.

    Babbage had friends and associates amongst the reform-minded Benthamites. He even sent his children to a school founded on utilitarian principles (Hyman 1982).

  5. 5.

    Incidentally, Babbage noticed that in factories with an extensive division of labour most of the operations were paid by piece work. This is presumably due to the fact that the work itself is more easily measured, although Babbage does not make this point.

  6. 6.

    The length of apprenticeships reflected both the time required for learning and the time required to repay to the master the losses he incurred during the learning process. If the time during which the master made losses fell as a result of specialisation, competition would ensure that the time during which he recouped losses would also fall. The facility of acquiring a skill and the possibility of entering a profitable employment at a young age would encourage entry into the trade with a resulting fall in wages.

  7. 7.

    As Babbage put it: ‘The exact ratio which is more profitable for a factory employing a hundred workmen, may not be quite the best where there are five hundred; and the arrangements of both may probably admit of variations, without materially increasing the cost of their produce’ (ibid.: 212).

  8. 8.

    Babbage regarded his recognition that a cause which at first sight might appear to be insignificant could have important consequences as one of his important insights which he highlighted in the introduction to The Exposition of 1851. He illustrated this point with the example of a workman raising his shovel an inch or two higher than was optimal. In the course of a day, this would produce a very sizeable difference either in fatigue or in the amount of work done (Babbage 1851 [1968]: 3). In Industry and Trade, Marshall commented favourably both on Babbage’s example and his generalisation and credited him with having worked out in ‘a considerable way’ one of the chief ideas of ‘Scientific Management’ (Marshall 1919: 275–280).

  9. 9.

    Babbage had already arrived at this position when he wrote the long article for Encyclopaedia Metropolitana.

References

Cited Works by Charles Babbage

  • Babbage, C. (1826). A Comparative View of the Various Institutions for the Assurance of Lives. London: J. Mawman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babbage, C. (1829). ‘On the General Principles which Regulate the Application of Machinery to Manufacture and the Mechanical Arts’. Introductory Dissertation in E. Smedley, H.J. Rose and H.J. Rose (eds) Encyclopaedia Metropolitana. Volume 8. London: B. Fellowes: 1–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babbage, C. (1830) [1970]. Reflections on the Decline of Science in England and Some of its Causes. New York: Augustus M. Kelly.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babbage, C. (1832) [1835]. On the Economy of Machinery and Manufactures. Fourth edition. London: Charles Knight.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babbage, C. (1837) [1838]. Ninth Bridgewater Treatise, A Fragment. Second edition. London: John Murray.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babbage, C. (1848) [1851]. Thoughts on the Principles of Taxation with Reference to a Property Tax and its Exceptions. Second edition. London: John Murray.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babbage, C. (1851) [1968]. The Exposition of 1851. London: Frank Cass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babbage, C. (1864). A Chapter on Street Nuisances. Second edition. London: John Murray.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babbage, C. (1864) [1991]. Passages from the Life of a Philosopher. Edited by M. Campbell-Kelly. London: Pickering & Chatto.

    Google Scholar 

Other Cited Works

  • Braverman, H. (1974). Labor and Monopoly Capital: The Degradation of Work in the Twentieth Century. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell-Kelly, M. (1994). ‘Charles Babbage and the Assurance of Lives’. IEEE Annals of the History of Computing, 16(3): 5–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Marchi, N.B. and R.P. Sturges (1973). ‘Malthus and Ricardo’s Inductivist Critics: Four Letters to William Whewell’. Economica, 40(160): 379–393.

    Google Scholar 

  • The Engineer (1871). ‘Murchison and Babbage’. 27 October: 284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enros, P.C. (1983). ‘The Analytical Society (1812–1813): Precursor of the Renewal of Cambridge Mathematics’. Historia Mathematica, 10(1): 24–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Geary, F. and R. Prendergast (2008). ‘Philosophers and Practical Men: Charles Babbage, Irish Merchants and the Economics of Information’. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 15(4): 571–594.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, J.P. (1996). Early Mathematical Economics: William Whewell and the British Case. London: Rowman & Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hyman, A. (1982). Charles Babbage: Pioneer of the Computer. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1919). Industry and Trade. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1959). Principles of Economics. Eighth edition. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. (1867) [1977]. Capital. Volume I. London: Lawrence & Wishart.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCulloch, J.R. (1833). ‘Babbage on Machinery and Manufactures’. Edinburgh Review, 56: 313–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill, J.S. (1848) [1973]. Principles of Political Economy. Clifton: Augustus M. Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rashid, S. (1979). ‘Richard Jones and Baconian Historicism at Cambridge’. Journal of Economic Issues, 13(1): 159–173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romano, R.M. (1982). ‘The Economic Ideas of Charles Babbage’. History of Political Economy, 14(3): 385–404.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1994). ‘Charles Babbage: Pioneer Economist’. Chapter 2 in Exploring the Black Box: Technology, Economics, and History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 24–46.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schaffer, S. (2003). ‘Paper and Brass: The Lucasian Professorship 1820–39’. Chapter 6 in K.C. Knox and R. Noakes (eds) From Newton to Hawking. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 241–293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J.A. (1961). History of Economic Analysis. Fourth printing. George Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, L.J. (2011). The Philosophical Breakfast Club. New York: Broadway Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1991). ‘Charles Babbage (1791 + 200 = 1991)’. Journal of Economic Literature, 29(3): 1,149–1,152.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Renee Prendergast .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Prendergast, R. (2017). Charles Babbage (1791–1871). In: Cord, R. (eds) The Palgrave Companion to Cambridge Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-41233-1_13

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-137-41233-1_13

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-137-41232-4

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-137-41233-1

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics