Skip to main content

Is Regional Science Just Economics with a “dij” Added to All Equations? Some Thoughts of an Economist

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Development Studies in Regional Science

Part of the book series: New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives ((NFRSASIPER,volume 42))

Abstract

This chapter looks at the extent to which “regional science” is distinctive enough to be called a unique sub-discipline. It considers the background against which the idea of a regional science was initiated and at the publications, institutions, and work that has been associated with the idea. In particular, it reviews the ways the American Economic Association has sought over the years to embrace geographical spatial analysis with the larger body of economic thinking. But this still leaves open the question of whether location and distance are really that different to the numerous elements included in modern economic analysis. The chapter looks at whether, even if there were a justification for a regional science in the 1950s, this has evaporated as economic thinking and analysis has morphed into something more integrated with other areas of social analysis. The conclusions reached are that even at the outset the notion of a specific regional science was vague and added little to what regional and urban economists were discussing. And even if differences could have been detected 75 years ago, these have now evaporated.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 119.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Other notable retrospective collections are the July 2007 issue of Regional Science and Urban Economics that reflects on 35 years of the journal and the April 2012 special issues of the Journal of Regional Science that assess the then state of spatial econometrics.

  2. 2.

    I focus mainly here on the situation in the USA. There were similar debates taking place elsewhere and especially in the UK from the mid-1980s when the Government’s Research Assessment Exercise was introduced across all disciplines to assist in the award of university grants. A defined subject specialism of an academic department, as well as the quality of the faculty, affected allocations of resources.

  3. 3.

    There was a considerable argument over the positioning of economic geography. Fritz Machlup, the international economist, along with some others, felt it should be split between “Area Studies” and “International Economics” on the basis that it entailed comparative analysis.

  4. 4.

    Edwin Mills, an innovator in the new urban economics, provided blueprints for the organization of “Urban, Rural, and Regional Economics” classification, and Richard Muth, another with an interest in NUE, was consulted on urban economics.

  5. 5.

    In his Principles of Economics, Marshall (1890) does include a specific chapter on “The concentration of specialized industries in particular localities” as well as introducing space and geography into a variety of economic discussions.

  6. 6.

    It was also about this time, in 1946, when, for similar reasons, the Transportation and Public Utilities Group was formed as the first associated organization to the AEA by economists such as James Nelson, Charles Dearing, and Ralph Dewey who were interested in those subjects.

  7. 7.

    Isard (2003) provides a more detailed account, while Barnes (2003) offers a critical assessment. It should perhaps be noted that Isard himself seemed to publish in economics journal in the early 1950s, e.g., Isard (1951).

  8. 8.

    One might also argue that the early 1950s was also the time that the embryonic ideas of regional multipliers, regional input-output analysis, regional trade-theory, etc. were laid down, albeit initially in the context of “national regions” rather than “economic regions.”

  9. 9.

    In fact, the inter-war theoretical literature had already said quite a bit on the effect of space on industrial organization – e.g., Hotelling (1929) on oligopolies and Chamberlain (1933) on monopolistic competition.

  10. 10.

    Meyer also footnotes that Isard’s book “constitutes a good single-volume introduction to regional economics… .”

  11. 11.

    This complaint is more difficult to make now since the founding of numerous national and sub-national Regional Science Associations and of the Regional Science Association International.

  12. 12.

    Kristian Behrens and Jacques Thisse (2007) make the salient point “… regardless of what is meant by a region, the concept is useful if and only if a region is part of a broader network through which various types of interactions occur. Without taking this aspect into account, one may wonder what the difference between regional economics and the macroeconomics of a closed economy would be.”

  13. 13.

    Jean Paelinck seems to have originated the term “spatial econometrics” in 1974. Moran’s (1948) work is generally considered the origin of spatial autocorrelation analysis.

  14. 14.

    If Isard did have a case for highlighting regional economic issues in the 1950s, it was on the grounds of inadequate official data collection rather than any intellectual neglect by the AEA. Richard Stone (1961) offers observations on the UK data situation in the 1950s.

  15. 15.

    This is one reason why local case studies have been a pronounced feature of regional studies where, unlike regional science, overriding laws are not sought.

  16. 16.

    In fact, Isard had wanted to call it “spatial science” but felt this would confuse it with physics and astronomy.

  17. 17.

    Here we talk about social science in the way Lionel Robins (1932) does.

  18. 18.

    Some transportation economists have in the past discussed the idea of using time (hours or minutes) as a measure of value on the basis that it is more equitable. It never gained acceptance.

  19. 19.

    There are programming techniques, such as data envelopment analysis, that are not limited to a single unit of measurement and that have a fairly long pedigree in economics, although admittedly not often used in spatial analysis. John Hicks (1960) provides an early general survey of some of these.

  20. 20.

    John Maynard Keynes gives a more complete reason, “I also want to emphasise strongly the point about economics being a moral science. I mentioned before that it deals with introspection and with values. I might have added that it deals with motives, expectations, psychological uncertainties. One has to be constantly on guard against treating the material as constant and homogeneous in the same way that the material of the other sciences, in spite of its complexity, is constant and homogeneous” (Letter to Roy Harrod, 10th July 1938).

  21. 21.

    This is very much in line with Mario Polèse’s (1995) argument that the fact regions are very distinctive makes generalization along traditional scientific lines extraordinarily difficult. In a nutshell, one should focus on individual regions.

  22. 22.

    In particular, the new institutional economics associated with the likes of Oliver Williamson (2000) have provided positive theories allowing a richer range of economic hypothesis to be explored.

  23. 23.

    Other papers include Chang and Li (2017) who replicated 22 of 67 economics papers that used the authors’ data and code files and additional 7 papers with assistance from the authors. Of articles using public data and making use of code written for software owned by the authors, 29 of 59 could be replicated. Replication has also involved several economic fields; Camerer et al. (2016) sought to replicate papers in experimental economics, Hamermesh (2017) labor economics, and Sandip Sukhtankar (2017) development economics.

  24. 24.

    Edward Leamer (1983) highlights “p-hacking.” “The econometric art as it is practiced at the computer terminal involves fitting many, perhaps thousands, of statistical models. One or several that the researcher finds pleasing are selected for reporting purposes. This research for a model is often well intended, but there can be no doubt that such a specification search invalidates the traditional theories of inference.” The situation was put bluntly by the Nobel Prize winner, Ronald Coase (cited in Gordon Tullock 2001), when he joked, “If you torture the data long enough, Nature will confess.”

  25. 25.

    The proportion may be even larger. Those not recording a specific department are classified as noneconomists.

  26. 26.

    Isard (1956) argues that economics, “…rarely obtains depth of analysis in that area which touches upon the broad influence of space and physical environment upon man’s behaviour and land utilization patterns.”

  27. 27.

    The Nobel speeches of Richard Thaler (2018) and Vernon Smith (2003), respectively, highlight the nature of these approaches.

References

  • Anderson RG, Kichkha A (2017) Replication, meta-analysis, and research synthesis in economics. Am Econ Rev 107:56–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnes TJL (2003) What’s wrong with American regional science? A view from science studies. Can J Reg Sci 26:2–26

    Google Scholar 

  • Behrens K, Thisse J-F (2007) Regional economics: a new economic geography perspective. Reg Sci Urban Econ 37:457–465

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry J, Coffman LC, Hanley D, Gihleb R, Wilson AJ (2017) Assessing the rate of replication in economics. Am Econ Rev 107:27–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyce D (2004) A short history of the field of regional science. Pap Reg Sci 83:31–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown AJ (1969) Survey in applied economics: regional economics. Econ J 68:761–796

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown AJ, Woodward VH (1969) Regional social accounts for the United Kingdom. Rev Income Wealth 15:335–347

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown DM (1979) The location decision of the firm: an overview of theory and evidence. Papers of the Regional Science Association 43:23–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Button KJ (2000) Where did the “new urban economics” go after 25 years? In: Regiani A (ed) Spatial economic science: new Frontiers in theory and methodology. Springer, Berlin, pp 30–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer CF, Dreber A, Forsell E, Ho T-H, Huber J, Johannesson M, Kirchler M, Almenberg J, Altmejd A, Chan T, Heikensten E, Holzmeister F, Imai T, Isaksson S, Nave G, Pfeiffer T, Razen M, Wu H (2016) Evaluating replicability of laboratory experiments in economics. Science 351:1433–1436

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlain E (1933) The theory of monopolistic competition: a re-orientation of the theory of value. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang AC, Li P (2017) A preanalysis plan to replicate sixty economics research papers that worked half of the time. Am Econ Rev 107:60–64

    Google Scholar 

  • Cherrier B (2017) Classifying economics: a history of the JEL codes. J Econ Lit 55:545–579

    Google Scholar 

  • Clemens MA (2017) The meaning of failed replications: a review and proposal. J Econ Surv 31:326–342

    Google Scholar 

  • Corrado L, Fingleton B (2012) Where is the economics in spatial econometrics? J Reg Sci 52:210–239

    Google Scholar 

  • Duvendack M, Palmer-Jones R, Reed ER (2017) What is meant by ‘replication’ and why does it encounter resistance in economics? Am Econ Rev 107:46–51

    Google Scholar 

  • Flyvbjerg B, Holm, MKS, Buhl SL (2005) How (in)accurate are demand forecasts in public works projects? The case of transportation. J Am Plan Ass 71:131–146

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1953) The methodology of positive economics. In: Friedman M (ed) Essays in positive economics. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 3–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Krugman P (2003) The new economic geography: past, present and the future. Pap Reg Sci 83(1):139–164

    Google Scholar 

  • Fujita M, Krugman P, Venables A (1991) The spatial economy: cities, regions and international trade. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Giarratani F (1995) Nurture the symbiosis between economics and regional science (It’s worth the trouble). Int Reg Sci Rev 17:343–346

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbons S, Overman HG (2012) Mostly pointless spatial econometrics? J Reg Sci 52:172–191

    Google Scholar 

  • Giesecke JA, Madden JR (2013) Regional computable general equilibrium modeling. In: Dixon PB, Jorgenson DW (eds) Handbook of computable general equilibrium modeling, vol 1. Elsevier, Oxford, pp 379–475

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh DS (2007) Viewpoint: replication in economics. Can J Econ 40:715–733

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh DS (2017) Replication in labor economics: evidence from data, and what it suggests. Am Econ Rev 107:37–40

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen N (1995) Regional science, regional policy, and the “new” regional economics: future possibilities in historical perspective. Int Reg Sci Rev 17:337–342

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1960) Linear theory. Econ J 70:671–709

    Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling H (1929) Stability in competition. Econ J 39:41–57

    Google Scholar 

  • Höffler JH (2017) Replication and economics journal policies. Am Econ Rev 107:52–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Isard W (1951) International and interregional input-output analysis; A model of a space-economy. Rev Econ Stat 33:318–328

    Google Scholar 

  • Isard W (1956) Regional science, the concept of a region, and regional structure. Papers and Proceedings of the Regional Science Association 2:13–26

    Google Scholar 

  • Isard W (1960) Methods and regional analysis: an introduction to regional science. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Isard W (2003) History of regional science and the regional science association international: the beginnings and early history. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Isserman AM (1995) The history, status, and future of regional science: an American perspective. Int Reg Sci Rev 17:249–296

    Google Scholar 

  • Isserman AM (2004) Intellectual leaders of regional science: a half-century citation study. Pap Reg Sci 83:91–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Kane EJ (1984) Why journal editors should encourage the replication of applied econometrics research. Q J Bus Econ 23:3–8

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman PR (1991) Increasing returns and economic geography. J Polit Econ 99:483–499

    Google Scholar 

  • Leamer EE (1983) Let’s take the con out of econometrics. Am Econ Rev 73:31–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Leontief WW (1953) Interregional theory. In: Leontief WW et al (eds) Studies in the structure of the American economy theoretical and empirical explorations in input-output analysis. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 93–115

    Google Scholar 

  • Maniadis Z, Tufano F, List JA (2017) To replicate or not to replicate? Exploring reproducibility in economics through the lens of a model and pilot research. Econ J 127:F209–F235

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A (1890) Principles of economics, 1st edn. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer JR (1963) Regional economics: a survey. Am Econ Rev 53:19–54

    Google Scholar 

  • Mills E, MacKinnon J (1973) Notes on the new urban economics. Bell J Econ Manag Sci 4:593–601

    Google Scholar 

  • Moran PAP (1948) The interpretation of statistical maps. J R Stat Soc Ser B 10:243–251

    Google Scholar 

  • Perloff HS (1957) Regional studies at U.S. Universities: a survey of regionally oriented research and graduate education. Resources for the Future, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Polèse M (1995) On the cultural origins and future direction of regional science: a voice from the periphery. Can J Reg Sci 17:311–318

    Google Scholar 

  • Richardson HW (1977) The new urban economics and alternatives. Pion, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Richardson HW (1978a) Input-output and economic base multipliers. Looking backward and forward. J Reg Sci 25:607–662

    Google Scholar 

  • Richardson HW (1978b) The state of regional economics: a survey article. Int Reg Sci Rev 3:1–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Robbins LC (1932) An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1954) The transfer problem and transport costs, II: analysis of effects of trade impediments. Econ J 64:264–289

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1776) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations, 1997th edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith VL (2003) Constructivist and ecological rationality in economics. Am Econ Rev 93:465–508

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiegel HW (1987) Jacob Viner (1892–1970). In: Eatwell J, Milgate M, Newman P (eds) The new Palgrave: a dictionary of economics, vol IV. Macmillan, London, pp 812–814

    Google Scholar 

  • Stewart JQ, Warntz W (1958) Physics of population distribution. J Reg Sci 1:99–121

    Google Scholar 

  • Stone JR (1961) Social accounts at the regional level: A survey. In: Issard W, Cumberland JH (eds) Regional economic planning. OECD, Paris, pp 263–296

    Google Scholar 

  • Sukhtankar S (2017) Replications in development economics. Am Econ Rev 107:32–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler RH (2018) From cashews to nudges: the evolution of behavioral economics. Am Econ Rev 108:1265–1287

    Google Scholar 

  • Tinbergen J (1962) Shaping the world economy an analysis of world trade flows. Twentieth Century Fund 5:27–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock G (2001) A comment on Daniel Klein’s ‘a plea to economists who favor liberty’. East Econ J 27:203–207

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (2000) The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead. J Econ Lit 38:595–613

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kenneth Button .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Button, K. (2020). Is Regional Science Just Economics with a “dij” Added to All Equations? Some Thoughts of an Economist. In: Chen, Z., Bowen, W.M., Whittington, D. (eds) Development Studies in Regional Science. New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives, vol 42. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1435-7_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1435-7_3

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-15-1434-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-15-1435-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics