Skip to main content

Estimating US Antidumping/Countervailing Duty Enforcement Benefits

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 556 Accesses

Part of the book series: New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives ((NFRSASIPER,volume 42))

Abstract

Dumping is the unfair trade practice of a foreign firm exporting its goods at a price below the sales price in its home market or below its production cost plus markup. Dumping displaces production of similar commodities in the importing country, because its domestic producers have difficulty competing with the lower import price. Antidumping (AD) is a major Priority Trade Issue of concern to U.S. Customs and Border Protection (CBP), and its enforcement is undertaken in parallel with that of countervailing duties (CVD), tariffs on imported goods that offset subsidies for these goods in the exporting country.

We present a generalized analytical framework and then apply it to the estimation of the macroeconomic impacts on the US economy of AD/CVD enforcement. We analyze individual markets for commodities that are being dumped to estimate the direct effects, and then use the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) multi-country computable general equilibrium (CGE) model to estimate the total (direct and indirect) impacts.

Our findings indicate an economic welfare gain to the US economy, measured in terms of personal income, of $182.3 million from the $508.8 million AD/CVD duties levied in fiscal year 2014. The duties themselves represent no welfare gain, as they are merely a transfer from importing companies in the USA to the federal government. However, the duties do provide a basis for estimating the macroeconomic benefits of enforcement if we divide them into the economic welfare impacts. They indicate that for every million dollars of AD/CVD duties levied, US personal income is increased by $358 thousand by way of the various direct effects of increased production of domestic substitutes displacing imported goods and the net of various indirect effects relating to resource allocation and the terms of trade.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   119.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    There are several metrics that are often used to evaluate policies and practices. Two metrics that are widely cited are gross domestic product (GDP) and employment. However, when federal government agencies evaluate the economic impacts of changes in government policies or programs, they are directed by the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) to use different measures, referred to as “economic welfare,” that better capture changes in the economic well-being of the US public. These measures are also used by agencies such as the US International Trade Commission (ITC) to evaluate the impacts of trade policies. The measures are always expressed in monetary terms, and they closely correspond to how personal income and profits change after a policy or program change. We provide more details in Sect. 22.3.

  2. 2.

    Although CBP’s major task is revenue collection, it also performs audits, inspections of cargo, processing of entry summary forms, and scrutinizing importers to identify risks or investigate cases of antidumping. All of these functions help detect violations.

  3. 3.

    Note that, aside from duties, one could also examine the impacts of any dollar value of penalties or fees, if they are significantly large, on importers and the foreign companies exporting products that are AD violations. These penalties and fees can result from negligence (for failures to exercise reasonable care), gross negligence (for cases with actual knowledge or wanton disregard), or fraud (for voluntary and intentional violation) of the importers. In the context of benefit-cost analysis, the AD duties themselves, since they are paid by US importers, would be considered a transfer payment and would not be included in the calculation of the change in economic welfare. However, any fees paid by the foreign exporter are an infusion into the USA from outside and can be considered a net gain to the economy.

  4. 4.

    Another consideration of the effect of the AD duties is the duration that the AD duties are in effect. Based on the AD/CVD data for 2014, a few of the AD/CVD orders have been in place for as long as over 30 years. On average, however, the AD/CVD orders that were active when we conducted this study have been in place for about 10 years. Many economists consider that temporary AD/CVD duties might help correct the market distortion, especially for temporary protection. However, if a foreign country subsidizes a product indefinitely, it worsens its terms of trade relative to the importing country on a long-term basis. In such cases, many economists hold reservations about the strategy of distorting the domestic market by imposing AD/CVD duties when the misallocation effect from the dumping is otherwise felt primarily in the foreign country.

  5. 5.

    We know from the literature in other contexts that the corrective mechanism does not always have the intended effects. The classic example is placing a pollution tax on the output of a monopoly. While for a competitive firm, this causes the producer to cut back output to the socially optimal level, if the producer is monopolist, the pollution tax further induces the monopolist to restrict its output to garner a higher price in the market. This could either mitigate or exacerbate the dead-weight loss depending on whether the monopolist’s private profit maximizing price was above or below the socially optimal price level accounting for the negative externality of the pollution.

  6. 6.

    We thank an anonymous reviewer for helping us clarify and rename these effects.

  7. 7.

    CGE models are usually thought of as measuring indirect, or general equilibrium, effects. However, given their microeconomic foundations of production and utility functions, they can also be used to estimate direct effects.

  8. 8.

    Data on CBP detections of violations could be used to check the modeling results in terms of the extent of displaced US domestically produced counterparts generated by the tariff simulation. Any significant difference would necessitate the recalibration of some major production or consumption function parameters.

  9. 9.

    Various other strategic effects relating to expectations of AD policies in relation to importer pricing policies are beyond the scope of this study. Note that these behaviors relate not only to pricing but also to product quality and quantity strategies (see, e.g., Blonigen and Prusa 2015).

  10. 10.

    Terms of trade effects simply represent a transfer from one country to another and have zero net impact on world welfare.

  11. 11.

    The sector known as (imputed value of) owner-occupied dwellings was combined with other services to facilitate CGE simulation accuracy. Since this sector does not have import goods and the associated transport margins are all equal to zero, running the model with this sector included separately causes the “division by zero” error.

  12. 12.

    CVD duties compose 23.3 percent of this total.

  13. 13.

    The data on AD/CVD cash deposits were collected at the 10-digit HTS commodity level. We then aggregated the AD/CVD cash deposits to the GTAP-sector level and calculated the AD/CVD tariff rate (in percentage terms) by dividing the total AD/CVD cash deposits of that sector (presented in the second column of Table 22.1) by the sector import volume (in dollar terms) (presented in the last column of Table 22.1). The electronic equipment sector is a typical example of the difference between the calculated AD/CVD tariff rate at the GTAP-sector level and the 10-digit HTS commodity level. In Table 22.1, the AD/CVD tariff rate of the electronic equipment sector is 0.0374%. There are four 10-digit HTS commodities in the electronic equipment sector that were subject to AD/CVD in 2014. The majority of the AD/CVD duty in this sector was imposed on one commodity – HTS 8541406020 Solar Cells Assembled into Modules or Panels – with an implicit AD/CVD tariff rate of 2.763%. Although this is much higher than the weighted average AD/CVD tariff rate (0.0374%) calculated for the electronic equipment sector, it is still a moderate tariff level for the specific commodity. For the other three commodities, the implicit AD/CVD tariff rate is similar to or even lower than the sectoral weighted average level. Our weighting procedure to obtain the sectoral-level AD/CVD tariff rate is likely to ensure the correct terms of trade effect but may fail to capture properly the dead-weight burden of the resource misallocation. However, for future studies, splitting out commodities in the GTAP model that have relatively high AD/CVD tariff rates will help improve the accuracy of the analysis.

  14. 14.

    Note that the data reference year of the latest GTAP Model is of 2011. We apply the GDP deflator to transform the data to 2014 values to calculate the AD/CVD tariff rate.

  15. 15.

    From here on we will simply refer to the combination of AD/CVD duties as “AD” for short.

  16. 16.

    An inspection of the simulations for the electronic equipment, chemicals, and metal products sectors individually and the three sectors combined shows that the results are almost perfectly additive, indicating the results are essentially linear. This is not surprising given the small changes in AD duties we are simulating.

  17. 17.

    After including the economic gains from the collection of $72.46 million of recovered revenues from CBP VA reviews, the total economic welfare gain in terms of personal income is $204.6 million.

  18. 18.

    In FY 2014, it is estimated that 129 full-time equivalent (FTE) CBP employees were dedicated to the enforcement activities of AD/CVD regulations. This translates to an increase in personal income of $1.4 million dollars per CBP FTE staff member. Furthermore, the per FTE total personal income gain of AD/CVD enforcement corresponding to the full administrative cost of one CBP staff member, on average, is a ratio of $11.4:1 (see Rose et al. 2016 for additional details).

  19. 19.

    We also performed an analysis of imports of honey and of coat hangers from China that indicate that AD duties have in fact protected these two relatively smaller US industries from unfair trade practices that might have caused their demise (see Rose et al. 2016).

References

  • Adams P (2005) Interpretation of results from CGE models such as GTAP. J Policy Model 27:941–959

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Avetisyan M, Heatwole N, Rose A, Roberts B (2014) Competitiveness and macroeconomic impacts of reduced wait times at US land freight border crossings. Transp Res A 78:84–101

    Google Scholar 

  • Blonigen B, Prusa T (2003) The cost of antidumping: the devil is in the details. Policy Reform 64:233–245

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blonigen B, Prusa T (2015) Dumping and antidumping duties. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 21573, Cambridge, MA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boardman H, Greenberg D, Vining A, Weimer D (2001) Cost-benefit analysis: concepts and practice, 2nd edn. Prentice Hall, Upper Saddle River

    Google Scholar 

  • Burfisher ME (2011) Introduction to computable general equilibrium models. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Z, Haynes KE (2014) Transportation capital in the United States: a multimodal general equilibrium analysis. Public Works Manag Policy 19(2):97–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Czako J, Human J, Miranda J (2003) A handbook on anti-dumping investigations. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • De Melo J, Tarr DG (1990) Welfare costs of US quotas in textiles, steel and autos. Rev Econ Stat 72:489–497

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixon J (2017) The impact on Australia of Trump’s 45 percent tariff on Chinese imports. Econ Pap 36(3):266–274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixon P, Jorgenson D (2013) Handbook of computable general equilibrium modeling. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixon P, Rimmer M (2010) Optimal tariffs: should Australia cut automotive tariffs unilaterally? Econ Rec 86(273):143–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixon P, Rimmer M, Tsigas M (2007) Regionalising results from a detailed CGE model: macro, industry and state effects in the U. S. of removing major tariffs and quotas. Pap Reg Sci 86(1):31–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Findlay C, Warren T (eds) (2013) Impediments to trade in services: measurements and policy implications. Routledge, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer R, Mirman L (1994) Learning about enforcement: a model of dumping. J Econ Integr 9(2):214–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Francois JF, Arce HM, Reinert KA, Flynn JE (1996) Commercial policy and the domestic carrying trade. Can J Econ 29:181–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallaway M, Blonigen B, Flynn A (1999) Welfare costs of the US antidumping and countervailing duty Laws. J Int Econ 49:211–244

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP) (2015). https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/models/current.asp

  • Huff K, Hertel T (2000) Decomposing welfare changes in the GTAP model, GTAP technical papers. Purdue University, West Lafayette

    Google Scholar 

  • International Trade Commission. (ITC) (2015) Anti-dumping and countervailing duties in place, March 2015

    Google Scholar 

  • Kokoski M, Smith VK (1987) A general equilibrium analysis of partial equilibrium welfare measures: the case of climate change. Am Econ Rev 77(3):331–341

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis JD, Robinson S, Thierfelder K (2003) Free trade agreements and the SADC economies. J Afr Econ 12(2):156–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rimmer M, Dixon P (2015) Identifying the effects of NAFTA on the U.S. economy between 1992 and 1998: a decomposition analysis. Paper presented at the GTAP 18th annual conference on global economic analysis, Melbourne, Australia

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose A (2015) Macroeconomic consequences of terrorist attacks: estimation for the analysis of policies and rules. In: Mansfield C, Smith VK (eds) Benefit transfer for the analysis of DHS policies and rules. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, pp 172–201

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose A, Chen Z, Wei D (2016) Chapter 4: Estimating U.S. anti-dumping/countervailing duty enforcement benefits. In: Roberts B et al (eds) Economic analysis of priority trade issues, Final Report to the U.S. Customs and Border Protection, Center for Risk and Economic Analysis of Terrorism Events (CREATE). University of Southern California, Los Angeles, CA

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Customs and Border Protection (CBP) (2015) Priority trade issue: antidumping and countervailing duties. http://www.cbp.gov/trade/priority-issues/adcvd

  • U.S. Government Accounts and Office (GAO) (2012) Antidumping and countervailing duties: management enhancements needed to improve efforts to detect and deter duty evasion, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Adam Rose .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Rose, A., Chen, Z., Wei, D. (2020). Estimating US Antidumping/Countervailing Duty Enforcement Benefits. In: Chen, Z., Bowen, W.M., Whittington, D. (eds) Development Studies in Regional Science. New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives, vol 42. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1435-7_22

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-15-1435-7_22

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-15-1434-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-15-1435-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics