Skip to main content

Vertical Fiscal Imbalances and Its Impact on Fiscal Performance: A Case for Indian States

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Opportunities and Challenges in Development

Abstract

Vertical fiscal imbalance (VFI) is defined as the share of sub-national governments’ own spending not financed through own revenues. Theoretical and empirical literatures on VFIs have identified them as an obstacle to sub-national accountability and good fiscal performance. India is a decentralized economy where a marked distinction is made between the spending and revenue responsibilities between the Centre and states. However, spending decentralization has not always complemented revenue devolution, giving rise to huge VFIs in the states. This paper attempts empirically to examine the relation between VFI and fiscal performance for Indian states. It provides stylized facts on size, financing and long-run trend of VFI for 24 major Indian states. Panel data estimation for all those states, covering the period 1995–96 to 2014–15, reveals that on an average the primary deficit of the state governments decline by 15 percentage point of Net State Domestic Product (NSDP) for each percentage point decline in VFI.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Spending decentralization refers to assignment of expenditure functions to the lower tier of the government from the Centre.

  2. 2.

    Revenue decentralization refers to devolution of revenue-raising capability to the lower tier of the government.

  3. 3.

    A detailed list of union and state expenditure functions as mentioned in the Seventh Schedule of Indian Constitution is provided in Tables 4, 5 and 6 in Appendix.

  4. 4.

    A detailed list of union and state taxes as laid down in Seventh Schedule of Constitution of India is provided in Tables 7 and 8 in Appendix.

  5. 5.

    Special category states are certain disadvantaged states with preferential treatment in the form of central assistance and tax break.

  6. 6.

    The criterion for tax devolution has varied from one Finance Commission (FC) to another. For example, prior to 11th FC, multiple criteria like collection, backwardness, poverty ratio were for devolving taxes. The 11th FC used population, distance, area, index of infrastructure, tax effort and fiscal discipline as the basis of devolution. The 12th FC, on the other hand, dropped index of infrastructure from the criteria.

  7. 7.

    The long-run trend of VFIs for individual states is provided in Fig. 7 in Appendix.

  8. 8.

    They defined fiscal balance as difference between general government total revenue and primary expenditure (i.e. expenditure net of interest payment).

  9. 9.

    Refer Fig. 8 in Appendix.

  10. 10.

    As suggested by the Finance Commission Reports.

  11. 11.

    Two constitutional amendment (73rd and 74th in the year 1993 and 1994) established mandatory provisions for decentralization to local governments in India. It envisaged the panchayat and municipal bodies as institutions of self-government. The states endow the lower-tier governments with powers and authority to enable the latter to function as institutions of self-government.

  12. 12.

    The literature suggests various definitions of decentralization. One of the most used is “share of sub-national expenditure to general government expenditure”. This definition of decentralization is inapplicable in the context of India due to the unavailability of comprehensive expenditure data at local and provincial governments. Thus, the use of this data can present an incomplete picture of the sub-national government. However, the expenditure responsibilities of all tiers of government, specifically the lower tiers, are mostly met through taxes and grants as recommended by the Central Finance Commission. Hence, the share of transfer of resources from Centre to own expenditure of the states might represent the degree of decentralization in India accurately.

  13. 13.

    Complete methodology given in Appendix.

  14. 14.

    One may argue that there are differences in the physical and economical characteristics of the two category states. Therefore, they are not directly comparable. Hence, we may get misleading results when the two category states are clubbed together. To get more accurate results, separate regression estimation is carried out for the general category states and special category states.

  15. 15.

    Clubbing general and special category states, together. Result is provided in, Table 11.

  16. 16.

    For alternate measures of VFI, fiscal performances and HFI, refer Appendix.

  17. 17.

    Refer Appendix, for robustness analysis results.

  18. 18.

    Refer Mukhopadhyay and Das (2003).

References

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baskaran, T. (2010). On link between Fiscal decentralization and public debt in OECD countries. Public Choice, 145(3–4), 351–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R. M., & Tarasov, A. M. (2004). Closing the gap: Fiscal imbalances and intergovernmental transfers in developed federations. Environment and Policy C: Government and Policy, 22(1), 77–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bird, R. M., & Vaillancourt, F. (2006). Perspectives on Fiscal Federalism. WBI Learning Series 35628, The World Bank, Washington D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R., & Tremblay, J. (2006). A theory of Fiscal Imbalance. FinanzArchiv, 62(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1980). The power to tax: Analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Mello, L. (2007). Local government finances: The link between intergovernmental transfers and net worth. OECD Economics Department Working Paper Number 581.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dholakia, A. (2005). Measuring Fiscal performance of states an alternative approach. Economic and Political Weekly, 40(31), 3421–3428.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dumitrescu, E. V., & Hurlin, C. (2012). Testing for Granger non-causality in heterogenous panels. Economic Modelling, 29(4), 1450–1460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eyraud, L., & Lusiyan, L. (2013). Vertical fiscal imbalances and fiscal performance in advanced economies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 60, 571–587.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodspeed, T. (2002). Bailouts in federations. International Tax and Public Finance, 9(4), 409–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagen, J., & Eichengreen, B. (1996). Federalism, Fiscal Restraints, and European Monetary Union. The American Economic Review, 86(2), 134–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herperger, D. (1991). Distribution of powers and functions in federal systems. Ottawa: Ministry of Supply and Services.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jin, J., & Zou, H. (2002). How does fiscal decentralization affect aggregate, national, and subnational government size? Journal of Urban Economics, 52, 270–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karpowicz, I. (2012). Narrowing vertical Fiscal imbalance in Four European Countries. IMF Working Paper WP/12/91. International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Le, T. M., Dodson, B. M., & Rojchaichaninthorn, J. (2008). Expanding taxable capacity and reaching revenue potential: Cross-country analysis. Policy Research Working Paper 4559. The World Bank, Washington, D.C.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ma, J. (1997). Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfer: A comparison of Nine Countries (Cases of the United States, Canada, the United Kingdom, Australia, Germany, Japan, Korea, India, and Indonesia). Prepared for Macroeconomic Management and Policy Division, Economic Development Institute. The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mohan, R., & Shyjan, D. (2009). Tax devolution and grant distribution to States in India. Analysis and road map for alternatives. Working Paper 419: www.sds.edu.

  • Muddipi, S. (1991). Finance commissions and centre state financial relations. Allahabad: ChughPublications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mukhopadhyay, H., & Das, K. K. (2003). Horizontal imbalances in India—Issues and determinants. Economic and Political Weekly, 38(14), 1416–1420.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. (1972). Fiscal federalism. New York: Harcourt-Brace. Chapter five.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. (1999). An easy on Fiscal federalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(3), 1120–1149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plekhanov, A., & Singh, R. (2007). How should government borrowing be regulated? Some cross-country empirical evidence. IMF Staff Papers, 53(3), 426–452.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rangarajan, C., & Srivastava, D. K. (2008). Reforming India’s Fiscal transfer system: Resolving vertical and horizontal imbalances. Madras School of Economics Working Paper 31/2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rao, M. G., & Singh, N. (2002). The political economy of centre-state fiscal transfers in India. In J. McLaren (Ed.), Institutional elements of tax design and reform (pp. 69–123).Washington DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rao, C. B., & Srivastava, D. K. (2014). Dependence of states on central transfers: State-wise analysis. NIPFP Working Paper No. 2014-137. National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New Delhi.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rao, M. G. (2000). Fiscal decentralization in Indian federalism. Retrieved from https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/seminar/2000/fiscal/rao.pdf.

  • Rodden, J. (2002). The dilemma of Fiscal Federalism: Grants and Fiscal performance around the world. American Journal of Political Science, 46(3), 670–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J. (2003). Reviving leviathan: Fiscal Federalism and the growth of government. International Organization, 57(4), 695–729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J., & Wibbels, E. (2009). Fiscal decentralization and the business cycle: An empirical study of seven federations. Economics and Policies, 22(1), 37–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharma, C. K. (2012). Beyond gaps and imbalances: Restructuring the debate on intergovernmental fiscal relations. Public Administration—An International Quarterly, 90(1), 99–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, N. (2007). Fiscal; federalism and decentralization in India. Paper Prepared for a World Bank project.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thirteenth Finance Commission Report. (2009).

    Google Scholar 

  • Velasco, A. (2000). Debts and deficits with fragmented fiscal policy making. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 105–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Data Source

  • Reserve Bank of India (RBI). Handbook of statistics on state finances. Mumbai: RBI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reserve Bank of India (RBI). Handbook of statistics on Indian economy. Mumbai: RBI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reserve Bank of India (RBI). Handbook of statistics on Indian States. Mumbai: RBI.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reserve Bank of India (RBI). State finances: A study of budgets. Mumbai: RBI.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Madhurima Koley .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10 and Fig. 7.

Table 4 Developmental functions included in the union lists in the Seventh Schedule of the Constitution
Table 5 Developmental functions included in the state lists in the Seventh Schedule of the Constitution
Table 6 Developmental functions included in the concurrent list in the Seventh Schedule of the Constitution
Table 7 Taxation heads assigned to the union in the Seventh Schedule of the Constitution
Table 8 Taxation heads assigned to the states in the Seventh Schedule of the Constitution
Table 9 Panel Granger non-causality test
Table 10 Result of Granger causality test (state-wise)
Fig. 7
figure 7

VFI—Evolution overtime for individual states 1. Andhra Pradesh, 2. Arunachal Pradesh, 3. Assam, 4. Bihar, 5. Gujarat, 6. Haryana, 7. Himachal Pradesh, 8. Jammu and Kashmir, 9. Karnataka, 10. Kerala, 11. Madhya Pradesh, 12. Maharashtra, 13. Manipur, 14. Meghalaya, 15. Mizoram, 16. Nagaland, 17. Orissa, 18. Punjab, 19. Rajasthan, 20. Sikkim, 21. Tamil Nadu, 22. Tripura, 23. Uttar Pradesh, 24. West Bengal

Regression-based Fiscal Capacity Approach of Measuring Horizontal Fiscal Imbalances (HFI):

Under this approach, fiscal/taxable capacity is the predicted tax–NSDP ratio estimated from a regression. The estimation procedure takes into account the states’ specific characteristics which include economic, demographic and institutional characteristics.

The basic specification (as given by Le et al. 2008) is

$$ Y = f\left( {\text{GDP, Population, Trade, Agr, Corr, Bureau}} \right) $$

where

Y:

Tax or total fiscal revenue ratio to GDP

GDP:

GDP per capita (constant 2000 $US)

Population: Rate of population growth or age dependency ratio as a share of the total population

Trade: Trade Openness

Agr: Agricultural value added

Corr: Corruption Index

Bureau: Bureaucracy quality.

The problem of extending the methodology at state level in India is simply unavailability of the above-mentioned data for all states and over time.

Hence, this paper employs the following specification:

Y = f (Per capita NSDPcurrent prices).Footnote 18

Predicted fiscal capacity \( \left( {\widehat{\text{CF}}_{it} } \right) \) is then derived by running a panel fixed effect regression on the above-mentioned specification for the two groups of states, general and special category as:

$$ \widehat{\text{CF}}_{it} = \hat{\beta }\,{\text{NSDP}}_{it} $$

Then, HFI is computed as:

$$ {\text{HFI}}_{it} = \widetilde{\text{CF}}_{t} - \widehat{\text{CF}}_{it} $$

where \( \widetilde{\text{CF}}_{t} \,{\text{is}}\,{\text{median}}\,{\text{fiscal}}\,{\text{capacity}}\,{\text{for}}\,{\text{each}}\,{\text{year}} \).

See Table 11; Figs. 8 and 9.

Table 11 Regression result on relationship between VFI and fiscal performance for 23 major Indian states
Fig. 8
figure 8

Coefficient of variation of HFI 1/ across states over the period 1995–96 to 2014–15

Fig. 9
figure 9

Trends in Average HFI 1/

Alternate definitions of VFI and fiscal performances:

  1. 1.

    VFI Measure:

  1. (a)

    VFI = the ability of the state to finance their current expenditure from their own revenue source

$$ {\text{VFI}} = \frac{{{\text{Own}}\,{\text{Revenue}}\,{\text{Source}}}}{{{\text{Current}}\,{\text{Expenditure}}}} $$

Refer Rao and Singh (2002), Table 2 in Appendix and page no. 9

  1. (b)
    $$ {\text{VFI}} = \frac{{\frac{{{\text{Own}}\,{\text{Tax}}\,{\text{Revenue }}_{\text{SNG}} + {\text{Non}}\,{\text{Tax}}\,{\text{Revenue }}_{\text{SNG}} }}{{{\text{Combined}}\,{\text{Revenues}}}}}}{{\frac{{{\text{Revenue}}\,{\text{Expenditure }}_{\text{SNG}} }}{{{\text{Combined}}\,{\text{Revenue}}\,{\text{Expenditure}}}}}} $$

Refer Muddipi (1991).

Given VFI is detrimental to fiscal performance, the coefficients of VFI is expected to be negative.

  1. 2.

    As indicators of fiscal performance, the following measures are applied:

  1. (a)

    Gross fiscal deficit as a proportion of total expenditure of the states.

This measure is used as a component index of fiscal performance index as recommended by the Twelfth Finance Commission (Dholakia 2005).

  1. (b)

    Ratio of revenue deficit to revenue expenditure of the states

It reveals the proportion of current expenditure to the government financed by the current deficit.

  1. 3.

    HFI Measures:

HFI refers to differential fiscal capacities of the sub-national economics. It occurs when sub-national governments have different abilities to raise funds from their tax bases and to provide services. Given non-concurrence on any particular definition of HFI, the following alternate definitions are used.

  1. (a)
    $$ {\text{HFI = }}\frac{{{\text{State}}\,{\text{per}}\,{\text{capita}}\,{\text{NSDP}}_{{{\text{Current}}\,{\text{prices}}}} }}{{{\text{Average}}\,{\text{of}}\,{\text{highest}}\,{\text{three}}\,{\text{per}}\,{\text{capita}}\,{\text{NSDP}}_{{{\text{current}}\,{\text{prices}}}} }} $$

Given the definition of HFI used in the main paper, it can be categorized as high or low. Thus, we use dummy variable approach for HFI.

  1. (b)

    When HFI = Average of highest three per capita NSDPcurrent prices − State per capita NSDPcurrent prices

$$ \begin{aligned} {\text{HFI Dummy}} & {\text{ = 1, when Average of highest three per capita NSDP}}_{\text{current prices}} \\ &\quad > \,{\text{State per capita NSDP}}_{\text{current prices}} \\ & = 0 , {\text{ otherwise}} \\ \end{aligned} $$
  1. (c)

    When HFI = Difference between the fiscal capacity of each state and median fiscal capacity

$$ \begin{aligned} {\text{HFI}}\,{\text{Dummy}} & { = 1,}\,{\text{when}}\,{\text{fiscal}}\,{\text{capacity}}\,{\text{of}}\,{\text{each}}\,{\text{state}}\,{ > }\,{\text{median}}\,{\text{fiscal}}\,{\text{capcity}} \\ & = 0 ,\,{\text{otherwise}} \\ \end{aligned} $$

Recording HFI as a dummy variable makes the regression results more interpretable. It captures the influence of VFI on the fiscal performance of the states, in the presence of differential fiscal position among the states.

Robustness Analysis Results:

See Tables 12, 13, 14, 15, 16, 17, 18 and 19.

Table 12 Regression result on relationship between VFI (alternate measures) and fiscal performance for 14 major general category states
Table 13 Regression result on relationship between VFI (alternate measures) and fiscal performance for 10 major special category states
Table 14 Regression result on relationship between VFI 1/ and fiscal performance (alternate measures) for 14 major general category states
Table 15 Regression result on relationship between VFI 1/ and fiscal performance (alternate measures) for 10 major special category states
Table 16 Regression results—sensitivity analysis
Table 17 Regression results—sensitivity analysis
Table 18 Regression results with HFI as interaction term
Table 19 System dynamic panel data estimation results 1/

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Koley, M., Mandal, K. (2019). Vertical Fiscal Imbalances and Its Impact on Fiscal Performance: A Case for Indian States. In: Bandyopadhyay, S., Dutta, M. (eds) Opportunities and Challenges in Development. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-9981-7_12

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-9981-7_12

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-13-9980-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-13-9981-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics