Skip to main content

Administrative Performance and Legitimacy: An Elaboration Likelihood Approach to Competition Authorities in Japan and the United States

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 275 Accesses

Abstract

What determines the number of legal actions taken by competition authorities in Japan and the United States? The administrative performance of government agencies has been analyzed from a wide variety of perspectives.

This Chapter is based on Koki Arai (2012) “Administrative Performance and Legitimacy: An Elaboration Likelihood Approach to Competition Authorities in Japan and the United States.” Public Performance & Management Review, 36(1): 54–78.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Thanks for the mention of the theories of politician/bureaucracy interaction by anonymous referees.

  2. 2.

    Muris (1986) criticized the FTC for its lack of marketability.

  3. 3.

    The basis of this systematic analysis is seen in Krause (2008), whose analysis was based on the main administrative body’s risk preference (preference for risk/avoidance of risk).

  4. 4.

    Max Weber divides control supported by legitimacy into three categories: legal control, traditional control, and charismatic control (Inokuchi 2000; Weber 1972).

  5. 5.

    Some authors support one of three related views: correspondence with the established rules, public acceptance of the rules, and realization of the public interest (Sasaki 1999).

  6. 6.

    For further details, see the Senate hearings at http://judiciary.senate.gov/hearings/testimony.cfm?id=3700&wit_id=7670/. The settlement between the Justice Department and Microsoft may have lessened the antitrust authority’s legitimacy.

  7. 7.

    In addition, the European Parliament has greater influence on the European Commission and plays an important role in determining policies because it is elected and thus legitimately reflects public opinion.

  8. 8.

    The discussion here does not deal with the voluntary motivation effect, namely, that the high level of legitimacy an organization has in its administration creates “motivation,” improves the power of persuasion, increases internal productivity, contributes externally to the accumulation of information, and leads to earlier yielding by the opponent. It is important to study the authority’s behavior, but the focus here is on an outer index of related factors.

  9. 9.

    The data are from Japan Fair Trade Commission annual reports and Japan Fair Trade Commission (1997).

  10. 10.

    See Japan Fair Trade Commission (1997); annual reports of Japan Fair Trade Commission; and www.jftc.go.jp/pressrelease/01.may/01051604.pdf, accessed October 4, 2001.

  11. 11.

    Indeed, although many cases are the subject of scholarly articles, the total number of professional studies can create respect for the specific field of law enforcement. Legal professionals’ demographics are an index of professionals; however, it is difficult to estimate the ratio of antitrust lawyers.

  12. 12.

    This database in Japan records the details of books, including title, author, publisher, the names of libraries and bookrooms of universities that keep the books, as well as call numbers and other information. See http://webfront.nii.ac.jp and www.nii.ac.jp/ir/dbmember/bcat-j.html, accessed October 4, 2001.

  13. 13.

    The Antimonopoly Act states that “the purpose of this Act is, by prohibiting private monopolization, the unreasonable restraint of trade and unfair trade practices … to promote fair and free competition, to stimulate the creative initiative of entrepreneurs, to encourage business activities, to raise the level of employment and actual national income, and thereby to promote the democratic and wholesome development of the national economy as well as to assure the interests of the general consumers.”

  14. 14.

    On the other hand, the coefficient for Budget is very similar to that of the Personnel variable, so it was omitted.

  15. 15.

    It is important to test for nonstationarity of picking up the econometric specification. The ADF test and the KPSS test were used for the nonstationarity. Some variables do not have a unit root, but others do not have a clear indication due to sample number limitation.

  16. 16.

    The log-linear type equation performs better than log-log, hyperbolic, and is a simple multinominal equation from the viewpoint of adjusted R2 and AIC.

  17. 17.

    The number of Justice Department sources is available at www.justice.gov/atr/, accessed October 4, 2001.

    The ADF test and KPSS test are used for the nonstationarity. Some variables do not have a unit root, but others do not have a clear indication due to sample number limitation. See Table 4.

  18. 18.

    See the remarks by Secretary-General Itoda in the roundtable discussion “On recent cases of violation of the Antimonopoly Act,” Fair Trade, No. 513 (July 1993).

  19. 19.

    See ICN-CPI Work Plan 2008–2009, mentioned in www.georgemasonlawreview.org/doc/17–1_Sokol.pdf, accessed October 4, 2001.

References

  • Aghion P, Alesina A, Trebbi F (2004) Endogenous political institutions. Q J Econ 119(2):565–611

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banks JS, Weingast BR (1992) The political control of bureaucracies under asymmetric information. Am J Polit Sci 36(2):509–524

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besanko D, Spulber DF (1989) Antitrust enforcement under asymmetric information. Econ J 99:408–425

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cyrenne P (1999) On antitrust enforcement and the deterrence of collusive behaviour. Rev Ind Organ 14(3):257–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubnick M (2005) Accountability and the promise of performance: in search of the mechanisms. Public Perform Manag Rev 28(3):376–417

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisner MA, Meier KJ (1990) Presidential control versus bureaucratic power: explaining the Reagan revolution in antitrust. Am J Polit Sci 34(1):269–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein D, O’Halloran S (1994) Administrative procedures, information, and agency discretion. Am J Polit Sci 38(3):697–722

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldman S (1982) Economic self-interest and political behavior. Am J Polit Sci 26(3):446–466

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghosal V, Gallo J (2001) The cyclical behavior of the Department of Justice’s antitrust enforcement activity. Int J Ind Organ 19(1–2):27–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goddard M, Mannion R (2004) The role of horizontal and vertical approaches to performance measurement and improvement in the UK public sector. Public Perform Manag Rev 28(1):75–95

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordon R, Kornberger M, Clegg SR (2009) Power, rationality and legitimacy in public organizations. Public Adm 87(1):15–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrington JE Jr (2005) Optimal cartel pricing in the presence of an antitrust authority. Int Econ Rev 46(1):145–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heider F (1958) The psychology of interpersonal relations. Wiley, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Inokuchi T (2000) Dictionary of politics. Kobundo, Tokyo (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Japan Fair Trade Commission (1997) The history of 50 years of policies of the Antimonopoly Act. Kosei-Torihiki Kyokai, Tokyo (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Krause GA (1996) The institutional dynamics of policy administration: bureaucratic influence over securities regulation. Am J Polit Sci 40(4):1083–1121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krause GA (2008) A positive theory of bureaucratic discretion as agency choice. http://localgov.fsu.edu/papers/archive/krause_001.pdf

  • Maskin E, Tirole J (2004) The politician and the judge: accountability in government. Am Econ Rev 94(4):1034–1054

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moe TM (1987) An assessment of the positive theory of “congressional dominance”. Legis Stud Q 12(4):475–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moran MJ, Weingast BR (1982) Congress as the source of regulatory decisions: the case of the Federal Trade Commission. Am Econ Rev 72(2):109–113

    Google Scholar 

  • Moran MJ, Weingast BR (1983) Bureaucratic discretion or congressional control? Regulatory policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission. J Polit Econ 91(5):765–800

    Google Scholar 

  • Muris T (1986) Regulatory policymaking at the Federal Trade Commission: the extent of congressional control. J Polit Econ 94(4):884–889

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petty RE, Cacioppo JT (1981) Attitudes and persuasion: classic and contemporary approaches. Wm. C. Brown, Dubuque

    Google Scholar 

  • Petty RE, Wegener DT (1998) Attitude change: multiple roles for persuasion variables. In: Gilbert DT, Fiske ST, Lindzey G (eds) The handbook of social psychology. McGraw-Hill, New York, pp 327–331

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner R (1970) A statistical study of antitrust enforcement. J Law Econ 13:365–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rey P (2003) Toward a theory of competition policy. In: Dewatripoint M, Hansen LP, Burnovsky SJ (eds) Advances in economics and econometrics, vol 2. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 82–132

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ringquist EJ (1995) Political control and policy impact in EPA’s office of water quality. Am J Polit Sci 39(2):336–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ringquist EJ, Worsham J, Eisner MA (2003) Salience, complexity, and the legislative direction of regulatory bureaucracies. J Public Adm Res Theor 13(2):141–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sasaki T (1999) Lecture on politics. University of Tokyo Press, Tokyo

    Google Scholar 

  • Souam S (2001) Optimal antitrust policy under different regimes of fines. Int J Ind Organ 19(1–2):1–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Takase K, Kuroda T, Suzuki M (2001) Dokusenkinshiseisaku kunan no jidai no kaikoroku (Memoir during the difficult time of the Antimonopoly Law in Japan). Kosei-torihiki kyokai, Tokyo

    Google Scholar 

  • Tanaka K, Okada A (2000) Reform of central ministries and agencies. Nihon Hyoronsha, Tokyo (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber M (1972) Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft (Economy and society). J.C.B. Mohr, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitford AB (2008) A test of the political control of bureaucracies under asymmetric information. Rationality and Society 20(4):445–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood BD, Anderson JE (1993) The politics of U.S. antitrust regulation. Am J Polit Sci 37(1):1–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood BD, Waterman RW (1993) The dynamics of political-bureaucratic adaptation. Am J Polit Sci 37(2):497–528

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Koki Arai .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Arai, K. (2019). Administrative Performance and Legitimacy: An Elaboration Likelihood Approach to Competition Authorities in Japan and the United States. In: Law and Economics in Japanese Competition Policy. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-8188-1_12

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics