Skip to main content

Subsidy Competition Between Regions: An Extension to Cross-shareholding and Employment Concerns

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Advances in Local Public Economics

Part of the book series: New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives ((NFRSASIPER,volume 37))

Abstract

In this chapter, we investigate the relationship between firms’ regional location choices and the subsidy policies of regional governments in an imperfectly competitive third-market model. The seminal paper by Janeba (J Int Econ 44(1):135–153, 1998) has found that no subsidies are given to firms, and we check whether this result continues to hold when we extend the model in two ways. First, we incorporate the distributions of firms’ shareholders across regions to examine whether the difference in these distributions affects the zero-subsidy result. We demonstrate that even if firms’ shareholders are located in both regions, the zero-subsidy result continues to hold. Second, we consider the situation in which regional governments have concerns about the regional employment associated with firms’ locations, and we examine whether these governments’ consideration of employment affects the zero-subsidy result. We find that when regional governments have concerns about regional employment, the subsidy competition has no subgame perfect Nash equilibrium.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The seminal study of strategic trade theory is that of Brander and Spencer (1985). The model is called the third-market model since Brander (1995).

  2. 2.

    Throughout the chapter, single and double primes denote first and second differentiation, respectively, with respect to a variable.

  3. 3.

    \(s_{k}>0\) (\(s_{k}<0\)) represents a specific subsidy (tax).

  4. 4.

    More specifically, \(\alpha _{11}\) (\(\alpha _{12}\)) is the fraction of firm 1’s profit shared by region 1’s (2’s) residents, respectively, and, likewise, \(\alpha _{22}\) (\(\alpha _{21}\)) is the fraction of firm 2’s profit shared by region 2’s (1’s) residents, respectively.

  5. 5.

    In the original model, region i’s social welfare is \(W_{i} =pq_{i}-C_{i} =\widehat{\pi }^{i}\), which is equal to firm i’s profit before any subsidies. In contrast, in our extended model, social welfare is not necessarily equivalent to firm i’s profit before any subsidies.

  6. 6.

    Source-based taxation is assumed in Janeba’s (1998) original setting.

  7. 7.

    The subscripts of the profit function denote partial derivatives with respect to outputs. For example, \(\pi ^{1}_{2} \equiv \partial \pi ^{1}\!/\! \partial q_{2}\).

  8. 8.

    The second-order condition is \(\pi ^{i}_{ii} =2p'+p''q_{i}-C_{i}''<0\).

  9. 9.

    \(\pi ^{i}_{ii} =2p'+p''q_{i}-C_{i}'' < \pi ^{i}_{ij} =p'+p''q_{i}\le 0\).

  10. 10.

    Janeba (1998) investigated tax competition under an assumption that he similarly called limited cost divergence.

  11. 11.

    \(\pi ^{i}_{ii}<\pi ^{j}_{ji} \Leftrightarrow p'+p''(q_{i}-q_{j})-C_{i}''<0\). If demand is linear, that is, if \(p''=0\), then the above inequality always holds. If \(C_{i}(\cdot )=C_{j}(\cdot )\), the equilibrium outputs of the firms are identical, that is, \(q_{i}=q_{j}\). Furthermore, in this case, \(p'+p''(q_{i}-q_{j})-C_{i}'' =p'-C_{i}''<0\) holds.

  12. 12.

    This logic is quite similar to that of the Bertrand paradox when two firms with the same constant marginal cost engage in price competition in a homogeneous-good market. In the Bertrand paradox, the price is equal to the marginal cost in the equilibrium because neither firm can obtain positive profits by changing its price. Likewise, in the laissez-faire equilibrium, neither regional government can obtain more welfare by changing the subsidy level.

  13. 13.

    This assumption can be also interpreted as the constant existence of unemployment in each region such that firms’ labor demand can be always absorbed within each region.

  14. 14.

    Note that we do not consider the situation in which the subsidy is given to regional employees because we do not explicitly introduce labor income or utility into the model to keep the analysis simple.

  15. 15.

    Albert (1993) first classified the practice of capitalism in developed countries into two types: Anglo-American capitalism and Rhine (German-Japanese) capitalism. Aoki (1980, 1988) demonstrated that the objective of Japanese companies is endogenously determined by Nash bargaining between shareholders and employees. Several studies (Aoki 1990; Imai and Komiya 1995) regard German-Japanese firms as employee-controlled firms.

References

  • Albert, M. (1993). Capitalism vs. capitalism: How America’s obsession with individual achievement and short-term profit has led it to the brink of collapse. New York: Four Walls Eight Windows.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki, M. (1980). A model of the firm as a stockholder-employee cooperative game. American Economic Review, 70(4), 600–610.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aoki, M. (1988). Information, incentives and bargaining in the Japanese economy. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Aoki, M. (1990). Toward an economic model of the Japanese firm. Journal of Economic Literature, 28(1), 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bond, E. W., & Samuelson, L. (1989). Strategic behaviour and the rules for international taxation of capital. Economic Journal, 99(398), 1099–1111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander, J. A. (1995). Strategic trade policy. In G. Grossman & R. Kenneth (Eds.), Handbook of international economics (Vol. 3, Chap. 27, pp. 1395–1455). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brander, J. A., & Spencer, B. J. (1985). Export subsidies and international market share rivalry. Journal of International Economics, 18(1–2), 83–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bucovetsky, S., & Wilson, J. D. (1991). Tax competition with two tax instruments. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 21(3), 333–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, J., & Grossman, G. M. (1986). Optimal trade and industrial policy under oligopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101(2), 383–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, R. H. (1992). Can capital income taxes survive in open economies? Journal of Finance, 47(3), 1159–1180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haufler, A., & Stähler, F. (2013). Tax competition in a simple model with heterogeneous firms: How larger markets reduce profit taxes. International Economic Review, 54(2), 665–692.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E., & Krugman, P. R. (1989). Trade policy and market structure. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huck, S., & Konrad, K. A. (2003). Strategic trade policy and the home bias in firm ownership structure. Japan and the World Economy, 15(3), 299–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imai, K., & Komiya, R. (1995). Business enterprise in Japan: Views of leading Japanese economists. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Janeba, E. (1998). Tax competition in imperfectly competitive markets. Journal of International Economics, 44(1), 135–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morita, T., Ogawa, Y., & Ono, Y. (2017). Corporate tax competition in the presence of unemployment. The Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry, Discussion Paper, Nov. 2017, 17-E-118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ogawa, H. (2013). Further analysis on leadership in tax competition: The role of capital ownership. International Tax and Public Finance, 20(3), 474–484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors wish to thank the participants in the seminars of the Theory of Local Public Economics held at Aichi University, Kyoto Sangyo University, and Nagoya University for their valuable suggestions. This work was supported in part by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Numbers No. 16K03615 and No. 16H03612 (Kojun Hamada), No. 17K18563 and No. 17K03762 (Mitsuyoshi Yanagihara), and No. 15K03449 (Kojun Hamada and Mitsuyoshi Yanagihara). The authors are solely responsible for any errors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kojun Hamada .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Hamada, K., Ogawa, Y., Yanagihara, M. (2019). Subsidy Competition Between Regions: An Extension to Cross-shareholding and Employment Concerns. In: Kunizaki, M., Nakamura, K., Sugahara, K., Yanagihara, M. (eds) Advances in Local Public Economics . New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives, vol 37. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-3107-7_4

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-3107-7_4

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-13-3106-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-13-3107-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics