Skip to main content

Federalism, Party Competition and Public Expenditure: Empirical Findings on Regional Health Expenditure in Italy

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Advances in Local Public Economics

Part of the book series: New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives ((NFRSASIPER,volume 37))

  • 358 Accesses

Abstract

Since the ‘90s, Italy has experienced a considerable decentralization of functions to the regions. This transformation has been especially relevant for the National Health System that has de facto assumed a federal system design. The federal reform aimed to discipline public health expenditure that drains a substantial share of the budget of Italian regions and is among the main causes of the regional deficits. Political economic analysis, however, suggests that the impact of federalism on public expenditure depends on central and local government strategies to win the electoral competition. Results derived in this chapter indicate that political competition actually works as a tool of fiscal discipline, as it shows a restraining effect on public health expenditure.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Besley and Coate (2003) compare the costs of common pool effect with the benefits of internalization of spillovers deriving from centralization, showing that centralization leads a cooperative legislature to over-provide public goods. The reason is that local voters will strategically appoint representatives with high demand for spending. In Dur and Roelfsema (2005), that result is reverted when costs cannot be shared among districts (as in the case of environmental regulation or shelter provision to asylum seekers).

  2. 2.

    See, for example, Migué (1997), Mazza and van Winden (2002), Dur and Roelfsema (2005).

  3. 3.

    Guccio and Mazza (2005) provides a small survey of the empirical studies verifying the impact of political economic variables on the allocation and/or size of intergovernmental grants.

  4. 4.

    At that time, lower classes of some areas did not know Italian and spoke only dialects.

  5. 5.

    Revenue also derived from a tax on family income and the possibility to add, next to the national tax, a tax on income from land and buildings. This rule applied also to provinces and it represented the main source of tax return.

  6. 6.

    In the South the percentage of people entitled to vote was half compared to Northeast. Only in 1912 universal suffrage was extended to the male population, and in 1946 also to the female population.

  7. 7.

    In 1949 it represented less than 13% of national expenditure.

  8. 8.

    The right to vote had been extended to the whole population.

  9. 9.

    In the 1960s the cost of collecting taxes on consumption, as a percentage of the total tax income, corresponded to more than 18%, six times more expensive than the cost to collect the homologous national tax on business.

  10. 10.

    Tax bases on land and buildings were checked by the land register and were updated with delay and without connection to inflation, also because of the electoral pressure of interested taxpayers.

  11. 11.

    It took more than 20 years after their creation to have them implemented.

  12. 12.

    Successively, the Constitutional Court extended the exclusion to self-employment earned income.

  13. 13.

    There was a common tax rate of 4%, but in 1996 municipalities got the power to increase it (within the ceiling of 7%) and to allow for tax exemptions and tax breaks.

  14. 14.

    In 1994, public debt reached 121.5% compared to 41% of 1970.

  15. 15.

    The Constitutional Court admitted them only as an extraordinary measure.

  16. 16.

    Although, there are not official data about the respect of the rules set, in 2006 18% of municipalities, among those that provided information, were not complying with the rules of the Pact.

  17. 17.

    This part does not take into account the law n. 42 of 2009, which is however not relevant for the empirical analysis in this chapter.

  18. 18.

    Penalties include the automatic increase of tax rates, the impossibility to enrol personnel or to make discretionary expenses, as well as penalties for governmental or administrative bodies.

  19. 19.

    It is still unclear how to define investment expenditures: wide definitions allow for inefficient behaviour, but strict definitions risk limiting investments in human resources. In the past, sub-national governments used to finance also current expenditure through debts, but now the Constitution forbids it. This prohibition, however, can be eluded, though temporarily, delaying the payment to firms providing goods and services to public administrations. Thus, governments with financial problems have highly increased their debt load for current expenditures especially in the health sector. Their difficulties have worsened and they have exerted strong pressure to get help from higher levels of government, worried about the spread of financial problems among firms for which public administrations are the main, if not unique, client. Another form of elusion of this prohibition results from the negative impact of disputes with creditor firms or employees about wage increases, which generate further costs.

  20. 20.

    The SSN was originally organized on the basis of a strictly vertical three tier structure of government: central (Ministry of Health), regional (20 Regional Health Authorities, RHAs) and local (local health agencies, Unità Sanitarie Locali, USL). A National Health Fund (Fondo Sanitario Nazionale, FSN) was created and financed mainly from general taxation, employer and employee payroll contributions, and a health tax levied on self-employed. The latter was determined annually by the central government and allocated up to down.

  21. 21.

    LEA covers all medical care considered to be necessary, appropriate, and cost-effective.

  22. 22.

    An overview of the Italian health care system, which includes the debate on the regional responsibilities is provided by France et al. (2005) and Ferrè et al. (2014).

  23. 23.

    For further details on the Italian health care financing system, see Bordignon et al. (2002).

  24. 24.

    The amount of funds transferred to or received from the FPN had to be determined according to a complex formula, allowing for the fiscal capacity of a region, its population size and age composition, its historic expenditure on health care, the size and the specific characteristics of its territory.

  25. 25.

    For Italy: Fedeli (2015); for Canada: Di Matteo and Di Matteo (1998) and Ariste and Carr (2001); for USA: Freeman (2003), Moscone and Tosetti (2010) and Wang (2009); for Spain: Costa-Font and Pons-Novell (2007),

  26. 26.

    Solé-Ollé and Sorribas-Navarro (2008) provide empirical support for the impact of partisan alignment in the allocation of intergovernmental transfers in Spain in the decade 1993–2003.

  27. 27.

    Levaggi and Zanola (2003) take into account also private health expenditure as an independent variable to investigate the relationship between it and public spending.

  28. 28.

    This reform has not been implemented simultaneously in each region but in different years, according to regional constitutions.

  29. 29.

    We exclude Trentino Alto Adige, an autonomous region where the responsibility of public health care is devolved at a provincial level.

  30. 30.

    In Italy, citizens have free choice of the region in which to obtain health care. Regions of residence financially cover their patients’ mobility.

  31. 31.

    See Greene (2003).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). Inefficient redistribution. The American Political Science Review, 95, 649–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., Danninger, S., & Rostagno, M. V. (2001). Redistribution through public employment: The case of Italy. IMF Staff Papers, 48, 447–473.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, C. (1995). The dynamics of public support for coalition governments. Comparative Political Studies, 28, 353–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ariste, R., & Car, J. (2001). Nouvelles considerations sur l´etude des determinants des dépenses de santé des gouvernements provinciaux au Canada: 1966–1998, Health Canada Applied Research and Analysis Directorate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atella, V., Belotti, F., Depalo, D., & Piano Mortari, A. (2014). Measuring spatial effects in the presence of institutional constraints: The case of Italian local health authority expenditure. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 49, 232–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1985). Public policies, pressure groups and deadweight cost. Journal of Public Economics, 28, 329–347.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Coate, S. (2003). Centralized versus decentralized provision of local public goods: A political economy approach. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 2611–2637.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bilgel, F., & Tran, K. C. (2013). The determinants of Canadian provincial health expenditures: Evidence from a dynamic panel. Applied Economics, 45(2), 201–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blazquez-Fernandez, C., Cantarero, D., & Perez, P. (2014). Disentangling the heterogeneous income elasticity and dynamics of health expenditure. Applied Economics, 46(16), 1839–1854.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyne, G. A. (1994). Party competition and local spending decisions. British Journal of Political Science, 35, 210–222.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bordignon, M., Mapelli, V., & Turati, G. (2002). Fiscal federalism and National Health Service in the Italian system of governments. In Annual Report on Monitoring Italy, ISAE, Rome.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bordignon, M., & Turati, G. (2009). Bailing out expectations and public health expenditure. Journal of Health Economics, 28, 305–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantarero, D. (2005). Decentralization and health care expenditure: The Spanish case. Applied Economics Letters, 12, 963–966.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantarero Prieto, D., & Lago-Peñas, S. (2012). Decomposing the determinants of health care expenditure: The case of Spain. European Journal of Health Economics, 13(1), 19–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coate, S., & Morris, S. (1995). On the form of transfers to special interests. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 1210–1235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costa-Font, J., Gemmill, M., & Rubert, G. (2009). Re-visiting the health care luxury good hypothesis: Aggregation, precision and publication biases? Health Econometrics and Data Group Working Paper 09/02, University of York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Costa-Font, J., & Moscone, F. (2008). The impact of decentralization and inter-territorial interactions on Spanish health expenditure. Empirical Economics, 34, 167–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costa-Font, J., & Pons-Novell, J. (2007). Public health expenditure and spatial interactions in a decentralized National Health System. Health Economics, 16(3), 291–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costa-Font, J., & Rico, A. (2006). Devolution and the interregional inequalities in health and health care in Spain. Regional Studies, 40(8), 875–887.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crivelli, L., Filippini, M., & Mosca, I. (2005). Federalism and regional health care expenditures: An empirical analysis for the Swiss cantons. Health Economics, 10(1), 20–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Devereux, M. P., Lockwood, B., & Redoano, M. (2007). Horizontal and vertical indirect tax competition: Theory and some evidence from the USA. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 451–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Matteo, L. (2003). The income elasticity of health care spending: A comparison of parametric and nonparametric approaches. European Journal of Health Economics, 4, 20–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Matteo, L. (2005). The macro determinants of health expenditure in the United States and Canada: Assessing the impact of income, age distribution and time. Health Policy, 71, 23–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Matteo, L. (2009). Policy choice or economic fundamentals: What drives the public–private health expenditure balance in Canada? Health Economics, Policy and Law, 4, 29–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Matteo, L., & Di Matteo, R. (1998). Evidence on the determinants of Canadian provincial government health expenditures: 1965–1991. Journal of Health Economics, 17, 211–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A., & Limão, N. (2008). A bargaining theory of inefficient redistribution policies. International Economic Review, 49, 621–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dur, R., & Roelfsema, H. (2005). Why does centralization fail to internalise policy externalities? Public Choice, 122, 395–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fedeli, S. (2015). The impact of GDP on health care expenditure: The case of Italy. Social Indicators Research, 122(2), 347–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferré, F., de Belvis, A. G., Valerio, L., Longhi, S., Lazzari, A., Fattore, G., et al. (2014). Italy: Health system review. Health Systems in Transition, 16(4), 1–168.

    Google Scholar 

  • France, G., Taroni, F., & Donatini, A. (2005). The Italian health-care system. Health Economics, 14(Suppl 1), 187–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Freeman, D. G. (2003). Is health care a necessity or a luxury? Pooled estimates of income elasticity from US state-level data. Applied Economics, 35, 495–502.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giannoni, M., & Hitiris, T. (2002). The regional impact of health expenditure: The case of Italy. Applied Economics, 34, 1829–1836.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. (2003). Econometric analysis (5th ed.). Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grisorio, M. J., & Prota, F. (2015a). The impact of fiscal decentralization on the composition of public expenditure: Panel data evidence from Italy. Regional Studies, 49, 1941–1956.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grisorio, M. J., & Prota, F. (2015b). The short and the long run relationship between fiscal decentralization and public expenditure composition in Italy. Economics Letters, 130, 113–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guccio, C., & Mazza, I. (2005). Analisi politico-economica del finanziamento regionale dei beni culturali. In A. Mignosa & I. Rizzo (Eds.), Gestione e valorizzazione dei beni culturali. Milan: Franco Angeli.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levaggi, R., & Zanola, R. (2003). Flypaper effect and sluggishness: Evidence from regional health expenditure in Italy. International Tax and Public Finance, 10, 535–547.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • López-i-Casanovas, G., & Saez, M. (2007). A multilevel analysis on the determinants of regional health care expenditure. A note. European Journal of Health Economics, 8, 59–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magee, S. P., Brook, W. A., & Young, L. (1989). Black holes tariffs and endogenous policy theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazza, I., & van Winden, F. (2002). Does centralization increase the size of government? The effects of separation of powers and lobbying. International Tax and Public Finance, 9, 379–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Migué, J. L. (1997). Public choice in a federal system. Public Choice, 90, 235–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moscone, F., & Tosetti, E. (2010). Health expenditure and income in the United States. Health Economics, 19(12), 1385–1403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Murthy, V. N. R., & Okunade, A. A. (2016). Determinants of U.S. health expenditure: Evidence from autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) approach to cointegration. Economic Modelling, 59, 67–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics. Explaining economic policy: MIT Press, Cambridge MA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porcelli, F. (2014). Electoral accountability and local government efficiency: Quasi-experimental evidence from the Italian health care sector reforms. Economics of Governance, 15, 221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, G. B., & Whitten, G. (1993). A cross-national analysis of economic voting: Taking account of the political context. American Journal of Political Science, 37, 391–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J. A., Eskeland, G., & Litvack, J. (2003). Fiscal decentralization and the challenge of hard budget constraints. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Solé-Ollé, A. (2006). The effects of party competition on budget outcomes: Empirical evidence from local governments in Spain. Public Choice, 126(1), 145–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solé-Ollé, A., & Sorribas-Navarro P. (2008). Does partisan alignment affect the electoral reward of intergovernmental transfers? CESifo Working Paper, 2335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stolfi, F., & Hallerberg, M. (2016). Clientelistic budget cycles: Evidence from health policy in the Italian regions. Journal of European Public Policy, 23, 833–850.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tucker, H. (1982). Inter-party competition in the American States one more time. American Politics Quarterly, 10, 93–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Z. (2009). The determinants of health care expenditures: Evidence from US state-level data. Applied Economics, 41, 429–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B., Shepsle, K., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 642–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B., & Wittman, D. (Eds.). (2008). The Oxford handbook of political economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1995). The myth of democratic failure. Why political institutions are efficient. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marina Cavalieri .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Cavalieri, M., Giardina, E., Guccio, C., Mazza, I. (2019). Federalism, Party Competition and Public Expenditure: Empirical Findings on Regional Health Expenditure in Italy. In: Kunizaki, M., Nakamura, K., Sugahara, K., Yanagihara, M. (eds) Advances in Local Public Economics . New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives, vol 37. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-3107-7_17

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-3107-7_17

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-13-3106-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-13-3107-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics