Skip to main content

Micro-foundation of Industry

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Microeconomic Theory

Part of the book series: Springer Texts in Business and Economics ((STBE))

  • 2233 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter introduces the standard equilibrium theory of industry. We focus mainly on the output market and later cover briefly the input market.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Even though a firm may decide to produce in the short run (when the firm is taking a short-term view), it may decide to leave an industry in the long run (when the firm is taking a long-term view).

  2. 2.

    A demand function is typically written as \( y = f (p) \), meaning that the quantity demanded y is dependent on the price. We often write \( y^{d} = f (p) \) to indicate it as a demand function. When this function f is strictly decreasing, we can also express the demand relationship by \( p = f^{ - 1} (y) \) or \( p = g (y) , \) where \( g \) is the inverse function. We call this the inverse demand function. Again, we often write \( p^{d} = g (y) \) to indicate that it is a demand function.

  3. 3.

    Rigorously, the revenue function is \( R (y) = \mathop \int \limits_{0}^{y} p (x) dx, \) implying \( MR (y) = p (y) \) for any \( y \ge 0 \).

  4. 4.

    In our definition, we implicitly assume that there are no external costs and external benefits. In this case, the demand curve is the marginal social benefit (MSB) curve and the marginal cost curve is the marginal social cost (MSC) curve. The social optimal point is where the MSB and MSC curves intersect.

  5. 5.

    The reactive equilibrium is defined by Riley (1979). Wilson (1977) defines the anticipated equilibrium, which is very similar to the reactive equilibrium.

  6. 6.

     The fact that each player acts in his own best interest does not automatically mean that the game is noncooperative. For example, the players may work as a team for the total surplus of a project, but they may compete for or react to their shares of the surplus in their own best interests.

  7. 7.

    We ignore the possibility that a consumer may not buy if the costs from both firms are too high. See Mas-Collel et al. (1995, p. 396) for a more general case in which this possibility is considered.

  8. 8.

    There is no loss of generality with this assumption as we can always name the firm on the left to be firm 1.

  9. 9.

    This is because, for \( x \in \left( {0, x_{1} } \right), \) if \( p_{2} + t\left( {x_{2} - x} \right) = p_{1} + t\left( {x_{1} - x} \right), \) then, for any \( \varepsilon \in {\mathbb{R}}, \) \( p_{2} + t\left( {x_{2} - x + \varepsilon } \right) = p_{1} + t\left( {x_{1} - x + \varepsilon } \right). \)

  10. 10.

    In this case, we need to include a participation constraint: the consumer is willing to buy a unit from firm i only if \( p_{i} + td \ge v, \) where is the consumer’s utility value from consumption of the product. See Mas-Colell et al. (1995, p. 399).

  11. 11.

    There are two standard models of spatial competition in the literature: the linear city model pioneered by Hotelling (1929), and the circular city model pioneered by Lerner and Singer (1939), developed by Vickrey (1964) and made popular by Salop (1979).

  12. 12.

    If an integer is needed, the equilibrium number of firms is \( \hat{n} = \left[ {n^{ * } } \right]. \)

  13. 13.

    Since a demand curve represents the maximum price (that the demander is willing to accept), a price ceiling is a ceiling on the demand curve. Since a supply curve represents the minimum price (that the supplier is willing to accept), a price floor is a floor on the supply curve.

  14. 14.

    Since the rental rate is low, the landlords may have less incentive to maintain housing quality, which may reduce demand further (a leftward shift of the demand curves). If this reduction is large enough, it may cause an even lower equilibrium housing stock.

  15. 15.

    We have drawn the MCP curve for a linear supply curve \( w (x) = a + bx \), which gives us some idea about the position of the MCP curve relative to the supply curve.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Susheng Wang .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Wang, S. (2018). Micro-foundation of Industry. In: Microeconomic Theory. Springer Texts in Business and Economics. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-0041-7_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics