Skip to main content

Institutions and Policy Making

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 470 Accesses

Abstract

Government policies and institutions are the driving force behind resource flows at the macro-economic level. This chapter examines the major policies and institutions that have directed the intersectoral resource flows, which ultimately have an impact on rural income as well as rural–urban income disparities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Some scholars have argued that the 1955 directive was issued in response to the huge influx of farmers into the cities (Liu, 2005).

  2. 2.

    Food rationing was abolished in 1993.

  3. 3.

    Regulations on Dealing with Household Registration Change, Ministry of Public Security, 1977.

  4. 4.

    Migration did take place during the Cultural Revolution (1966–1976), when many urban cadres, students and intellectuals were xiafang (sent down) to the countryside to be re-educated by the peasants. At the same time, peasant labourers were brought in for urban construction and industrialization. Therefore, this was a period of the huge exchange of urban and rural labour (Chan, 1994). As these peasant labourers were usually ‘temporary’ or ‘contract’ workers, they were not given an urban hukou and not categorized as the urban population, as described in Fig. 3.1.

  5. 5.

    Estimates of migrants vary in China, as most of them are unofficial and undocumented.

  6. 6.

    ‘Blue-stamp’ hukou was gradually phased out in different cities since 2003.

  7. 7.

    This practice was extended to all small towns and cities and, further, to some of the larger and capital cities in 2001.

  8. 8.

    The State Council and Ministry of Public Security in 1998 published ‘Several Comments on Some Predominant Problems Concerning Present Household Registration System’, which stipulated that: (1) children’s registration will follow either the mother or father depending on the decision of the parents (formerly, the children’s registration was with the mother); (2) there would be a further relaxation of the policies concerning separated spouses; (3) parents are able to follow their children by transferring their hukou to the cities where their children are living; and (4) investment and property purchase in the cities would be encouraged.

  9. 9.

    Interim Regulations Concerning Entry of Household Registration of Nanjiang City, Municipal Government and Public Security Bureau of Nanjing, June 19, 2004.

  10. 10.

    This was abolished in 2005.

  11. 11.

    Xinhua News, The Pearl River Delta Encounters Shortage of Migrant Labour, April 19, 2006.

  12. 12.

    Agricultural and related taxes were abolished officially from January, 2006.

  13. 13.

    The State Council, Management Regulations on Expenses and Labour Undertaken by Peasants, December 7, 1991.

  14. 14.

    Ibid.

  15. 15.

    Decision on Amendment of Income Tax Law of the People’s Republic of China, passed at 18th Session of the Standing Committee of the 10th National People’s Congress.

  16. 16.

    On December 29, 2005, the 19th Session of the 10th National People’s Congress Standing Committee passed the Decision to Abolish the Agricultural Tax Regulations of People’s Republic of China.

  17. 17.

    Minister of Finance’s speech during interview on December 29, 2005.

  18. 18.

    Speech made during interview by the Xinhua News Agency on December 29th, 2005.

  19. 19.

    In 1953, the Central Committee of the Communist Party of China and the State Council published Decision on Grain Compulsory Procurement and Sales and Order on Planned Procurement and Planned Sales of Grains.

  20. 20.

    The negotiated prices were lower than the market prices but higher than the contract prices.

  21. 21.

    Price average for the within and above quota prices.

  22. 22.

    The sovereignty of Hong Kong was handed over to the PRC in 1997.

  23. 23.

    Labour cost = living necessities for a labourer per year/(365 − days of rest)

  24. 24.

    It represents a welfare judgement, which cannot reflect the opportunity cost because commune members were paid evenly for their time spent on on-the-job leisure. From 1965–78, a daily labourer’s wages were set at 0.8 yuan.

  25. 25.

    Retail prices refer to the state retail prices, rather than the market prices. The market retail prices were always higher than the state prices.

  26. 26.

    State-owned enterprises were allowed to retain some of their profits since the 1980s.

References

  • Ahmad, E., Singh, R., & Fortuna, M. (2004). Toward more effective redistribution: Reform options for intergovernmental transfers in China (Vol. 4).

    Google Scholar 

  • Aubert, C. (1990). The agricultural crisis in China at the End of the 1980s. Remaking Peasant China: Problems of Rural Development and Institutions at the Start of the 1990s. Aarhus University Press, Aarhus, pp. 16–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aubert, C., & Li, X. (2002). ‘Peasant Burden’: Taxes and Levies Imposed on Chinese Farmers. Agricultural policies in China after WTO accession, 5, 160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, T. P., & Lü, X. (2000). Taxation without representation: Peasants, the central and the local states in reform China. The China Quarterly, 163, 742–763.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, R., & Tao, R. (2003). China’s labor market performance and challenges.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chai, P., Zhou, J., & Xie, J. (1999). Empirical study on the rationale of peasant’s burden. Issues in Agricultural Economy (12), 41–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chan, K. W. (1994). Cities with invisible walls: Reinterpreting urbanization in post-1949 China. UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chan, K. W., & Zhang, L. (1999). The hukou system and rural-urban migration in China: Processes and changes. The China Quarterly, 160, 818–855.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, X. (2003). Studies on finance at county and township level and rural income growth. Taiyuan: Shanxi Economic Publishing Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, G., & Wu, C. (2004). Survey on Chinese peasants. Beijing: Beijing People’s Literature Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duan, Y. (1986). Grain circulating system needs a major reform. Issues in Agricultural Economy (11), 37–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fang, C., & Chan, K. W. (2000). The political economy of urban protectionist employment policies in China.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fu, G. (2001). Survey reports on the taxes and fees shouldered by peasants in seven counties of Hubei Province. Issues in Agricultural Economy (4), 40–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guo, Y. (2002). The problem of overburden in rural areas in China. Journal of Peking University (Philosophy and Social Sciences), 39(1), 47–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hare, D., & Zhao, S. (2000). Labor migration as a rural development strategy: A view from the migration origin. Rural labor flows in china (42), 148.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jiang, C. (2004). The impact of financial difficulties at county and township levels on financial support of agriculture. Management World (7), 61–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, D. G. (1988). Economic reforms in the People’s Republic of China. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 36(S3), S225–S245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy, J. J. (2007). From the tax-for-fee reform to the abolition of agricultural taxes: The impact on township governments in north-west China. The China Quarterly, 189, 43–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khan, A. R. (1993). The determinants of household income in rural China. In The distribution of income in China (pp. 95–115). Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, J., & Song, L. (1999). The rural-urban divide: Economic disparities and interactions in China. OUP Catalogue.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lardy, N. R. (1983a). Agricultural prices in China (Vol. 1). USA: World Bank Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lardy, N. R. (1983b). Agriculture in China’s modern economic development. UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, L. (2012). Decomposing wage differentials between migrant workers and urban workers in urban China’s labor markets. China Economic Review, 23(2), 461–470.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, C., & Liu, C. (1997). Difficulties and possible solutions in the circulation of total social funds. Review of Economic Research, No. 1007, 2–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, X. (2003). Rethinking the peasant burden: Evidence from a Chinese village. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 30(3–4), 45–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liang, Z. (2001). The age of migration in China. Population and development review, 27(3), 499–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, J., Tao, R., Liu, M., & Zhang, Q. (2002). Urban and rural household taxation in China: Measurement and stylized facts. China Centre for Economic Research, Peking University, Beijing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, J. Y. (1988). The household responsibility system in China’s agricultural reform: A theoretical and empirical study. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 36(S3), S199–S224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, Y. (2003). Several viewpoints on the present rural policy. Issues in Agricultural Economy (6), 4–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipton, M. (1977). Why poor people stay poor: Urban bias in world development. London: Canberra: Temple Smith; Australian National University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Z. (2005). Institution and inequality: The hukou system in China. Journal of comparative economics, 33(1), 133–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lu, X. (1997). The politics of peasant burden in reform China. The Journal of Peasant Studies, 25(1), 113–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lu, Y. (2004). Empirical analysis on differences of tax and fee burden rates of rural households. Journal of Xinyang Normal University (Philosophy and Social Sciences Edition), 24(1), 40–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lu, Z., & Song, S. (2006). Rural–urban migration and wage determination: The case of Tianjin, China. China Economic Review, 17(3), 337–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma, J. (2000). Off-budgetary activities of China governments since economic reform. Paper presented at the 12th Annual Conference of Association for Budgeting and Financial Management, Kansas City, http://www.use.cuhk.edu.hk/wk_wzdetails.asp.

  • Ma, J., & Norregaard, J. (1998). China’s fiscal decentralization. Unpublished Manuscript. Washington: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2005). Review of agricultural policies: China. Beijing.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2006). Challenges for China’s public spending: Toward greater effectiveness and equity. France, OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Park, A., & Wang, D. (2010). Migration and urban poverty and inequality in China. China Economic Journal, 3(1), 49–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ping, J., & Bai, X. (2006). Fiscal Decentralization and Local Public Good Provision in China. Finance & Trade Economics, 2, 009.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riskin, C. (1987). China’s political economy: The quest for development since 1949. USA: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheng, Y. (1993). Intersectoral resource flows and China’s economic development. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solinger, D. J. (1999). Contesting citizenship in urban China: Peasant migrants, the state, and the logic of the market. USA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Song, L. (2000). Diversification of household production in rural China: The determinants and outcomes. Rural Labor Flows in China. Berkeley: Institute of East Asian Studies, University of California, pp. 101–128.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tao, R., & Liu, M. (2005). Urban and rural household taxation in China. Measurement, comparison and policy implications. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy, 10(4), 486–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, S. (1997). China’s 1994 fiscal reform: An initial assessment. Asian Survey, 37(9), 801–817.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, D. (2003). China’s rural compulsory education: Current situation, problems and policy alternatives: Working paper series.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, F.-l. (2005). Brewing tensions while maintaining stabilities: The dual role of the hukou system in contemporary China. Asian Perspective, 85–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, H., Guo, F., & Cheng, Z. (2015). A distributional analysis of wage discrimination against migrant workers in China’s urban labour market. Urban Studies, 52(13), 2383–2403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whyte, M. K. (2010). One country, two societies: rural-urban inequality in contemporary China (Vol. 16). USA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wong, C. (1995). Fiscal reform in 1994. China Review, 20(21-20), 13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wong, C. (2001). Fiscal Decentralization in China: The problematic outcomes of unplanned changes in transition towards a market economy. Bangkok: Paper presented at the Asian Development Forum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wong, C. P. (2000). Central-local relations revisited the 1994 tax-sharing reform and public expenditure management in China. China Perspectives, 52–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wong, K., Fu, D., Li, C. Y., & Song, H. X. (2007). Rural migrant workers in urban China: Living a marginalised life. International Journal of Social Welfare, 16(1), 32–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, X. (2011). The household registration system and rural-urban educational inequality in contemporary China. Chinese Sociological Review, 44(2), 31–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu, Y., & He, S. (1995). Comments on the current situation of public finance. Economic Reform and Development (8), 7–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang, X. (2000). Interconnections among Gender, Work, and Migration. In B. Entwisle & G. E. Henderson (Eds.), Red aw ng Boundaries: Work, Household, and Gender in China. Berkeley: University of California Press. ri, 197–213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang, Z., & Qu, S. (2005). A brief analysis on three policy changes of grain purchase and sales. Green Issues Research (2), 13–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yep, R. (2004). Can “Tax-for-Fee” reform reduce rural tension in China? The process, progress and limitations. The China Quarterly, 177, 42–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, Y. (2000). Rural-to-urban labor migration in China: The past and the present. Rural labor flows in China, 15, 33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, L., & Li, J. (2006). China’s hukou system: Multifaceted changes and institutional causes. In Discussion Paper, No. 9 (June), China Policy Institute, University of Nottingham.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yan Gao .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Shanghai Jiao Tong University Press and Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Gao, Y., Fennell, S. (2018). Institutions and Policy Making. In: China’s Rural–Urban Inequality in the Countryside. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-8273-3_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics