Skip to main content

A New Approach to Dynamic Externalities (I)

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
A New Perspective on Agglomeration Economies in Japan

Part of the book series: New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives ((NFRSASIPER,volume 20))

  • 395 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter investigates how dynamic externalities promote industrial growth in Japanese manufacturing industries. In contrast to previous studies, this study characterizes dynamic externalities by total factor productivity. Using panel data of Japanese prefectures from 1985 through 2000, this study finds evidence of localization (MAR) externalities and urbanization (Jacobs) externalities. However, this study does not find clear evidence that dynamic externalities play the role of centripetal forces for industrial location.

This chapter is based on Otsuka (2003) “Dynamic externalities in Japanese manufacturing industries,” Journal of Applied Regional Science (Vol. 8, No. 1, pp. 55–66, in Japanese).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    E is the spillover effects received from an agglomeration formed by individual producers in the same industry or different industries, and it incorporates technological progress embodied in the production factors, including the abilities of workers, the performance and quality of capital goods, and the quality of raw materials and intermediate input goods. This is in consideration of simultaneous growth, including from networks, externalities, complementarities, and economies of scale.

  2. 2.

    It is assumed that E does not affect the marginal productivity of the production factor J(=K , L , M).

  3. 3.

    Generally, constant returns to scale are not established in the short term since it is not easy to adjust capital equipment and labor. To address this problem, one approach assumes that, in the short term, all capital stock are fixed factors and labor is variable. On the other hand, there is the approach in Nishimura et al. (1999) that handles the organizational structure of a firm and the existence of managers as semi-fixed factors. Both suggest the existence of some types of fixed costs in the short term. In this study, the cost function is not specified, but regardless of the cost structure envisaged, it does not have a direct effect on the derivations (Basu and Fernald 1997, 2002).

  4. 4.

    According to Basu and Fernald (1997), the average profit rate of firms in imperfect competition is extremely small (approximately 3%). Klette (1999) estimated the margin rate for Norway’s manufacturing industries, also obtaining the result that the margin rate was extremely small, economically.

  5. 5.

    Although not explicitly shown in the model, the assumption that the profit rate is close to zero even under imperfect competition can be established by considering the existence of fixed costs.

  6. 6.

    Assuming firm i is facing perfect competition, that production has constant returns to scale, and there are no effects from externalities, (9) will be consistent with the Solow residual.

  7. 7.

    Since the R term in (6.16) includes the input growth of the industry and it is possible that it correlates with the explanatory variable, it is necessary to remove this term for the estimations. Therefore, there is no choice but to carry out a simplification that economies of scale in firms in the same industry are the same. If this simplification were not carried out, instrumental variables would be required in the estimations, but it would be difficult to find instrumental variables that do not correlate with the error term but do correlate significantly with the explanatory variable.

  8. 8.

    Henderson (1997) conducted research on externalities considering differences at points in time, and confirmed that externalities have a certain degree of continuity and demonstrate the existence of dynamic externalities.

  9. 9.

    From the results of the F test to consider individual effects, where the null hypothesis was that they do not exist, the null hypothesis was rejected in most of the industries at the significance level of 1%.

  10. 10.

    It is necessary to integrate the industry classifications when using data prior to 1985, but a new problem that arises in the process of integration is handling of concealment data.

  11. 11.

    Conventionally, urbanization economies are considered to occur in all industries in urban areas, but here, due to data constraints, all manufacturing industries in a region are assumed as a body of industrial agglomeration.

  12. 12.

    In this chapter, the possibility of series correlation is not considered. As it is an analysis of a log difference series, series correlations seem less likely to be a major problem compared to data level analysis.

  13. 13.

    Price markups tend to be linked to the business cycle. Refer to Hall (1988) for further details.

  14. 14.

    In other words, it is assumed that while each firm is a price taker in the production factors market, they face imperfect completion in the product market. However, Nishimura et al. (1999) used value-added production functions.

  15. 15.

    The main data source is the Nikkei Needs database, which is based on companies’ securities reports. As this is a database of listed companies, it is not consistent with the Census of Manufactures. To the best of my knowledge, there is no other research that attempted to estimate price markups at the firm-level, so it is adopted as the benchmark in this chapter.

  16. 16.

    Mano and Otsuka (2000) conducted empirical research into dynamic externalities targeting metal products, general machinery, electric machinery, transportation equipment, and precision machinery from within the two-digit manufacturing industry classifications using the 47 prefectures in Japan. The results of their analysis clarify that, in each industry, localization economies have a negative effect on growth. Based on the product cycle hypothesis, they explained the ground of locational dispersion in these industries.

  17. 17.

    In textile mill products and apparel, and other finished products made from fabrics and similar materials, the bias in the industrial distribution over time is noticeable. However, the rates of decrease in the number of establishments and employees in these industries over the analysis period were extremely high. For example, for the number of establishments and employees in textiles in 2000 compared to 1985, the rates of change were –67.6% and –71.2% respectively, which were the highest rates in all manufacturing industries. In apparel and other finished products made from fabrics and similar materials, these rates were –26.9% and –31.1%. These rates were high compared to transportation equipment (–3.3% and –11.2%) and as this industry is highly likely to transfer its bases overseas (particularly to China), it was judged unlikely that regional specialization within Japan would act as centripetal forces.

References

  • Basu S, Fernald JG. Are apparent productive spillovers a figment of specification error? J Monet Econ. 1995;36(1):165–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu S, Fernald JG. Returns to scale in U.S. production: estimates and implications. J Polit Econ. 1997;105(2):249–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basu S, Fernald JG. Aggregate productivity and aggregate technology. Eur Econ Rev. 2002;46(6):963–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero RJ, Lyons RK. Internal versus externalities in European industry. Eur Econ Rev. 1990;34(4):805–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero RJ, Lyons RK. External effects in U.S. procyclical productivity. J Monet Econ. 1992;29(2):209–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE. The relation between price and marginal cost in U.S. industry. J Polit Econ. 1988;96(5):921–47.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE. Invariance properties of Solow’s productivity residual. In: Diamond P, editor. Growth/productivity/unemployment: essays to celebrate Bob Solow’s birthday. Cambridge, MA/London: MIT Press; 1990. p. 71–112.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV. Externalities and industrial development. J Urban Econ. 1997;42(3):449–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klette TJ. Market power, scale economies and productivity: estimates from a panel of establishment data. J Ind Econ. 1999;47(4):451–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klette TJ, Griliches Z. The inconsistency of common scale estimators when output price are unobserved and endogenous. J Appl Econ. 1996;11(4):343–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P. Geography and trade. Cambridge, MA/London: MIT Press; 1991a.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P. Increasing returns and economic geography. J Polit Econ. 1991b;99(3):483–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mano Y, Otsuka K. Agglomeration economies and geographical concentration of industries: a case study of manufacturing sectors in postwar Japan. J Jpn Int Econ. 2000;14(3):189–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nishimura K, Ohkusa Y, Ariga K. Estimating the mark-up over marginal cost: a panel analysis of Japanese firms 1971–1994. Int J Ind Organ. 1999;17(8):1077–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Otsuka A. Dynamic externalities in Japanese manufacturing industries. J Appl Reg Sci. 2003;8(1):55–66. (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Oulton N. Increasing returns and externalities in UK manufacturing: myth or reality? J Ind Econ. 1996;44(1):99–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Otsuka, A. (2017). A New Approach to Dynamic Externalities (I). In: A New Perspective on Agglomeration Economies in Japan. New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives, vol 20. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-6490-6_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-6490-6_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-6489-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-6490-6

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics