Skip to main content

Household Vulnerability and the CCT Within the Risk-Sharing Framework

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Household Vulnerability and Conditional Cash Transfers

Part of the book series: SpringerBriefs in Economics ((BRIEFSKUSSRS))

  • 340 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter focuses on the empirical analyses of risk-sharing and household vulnerability to idiosyncratic shocks in rural Mexico. It aims to test the full risk-sharing hypothesis proposed by Townsend (1994), and to examine whether the conditional cash transfer (CCT) program reduces vulnerability within the risk-sharing framework using the same ENCEL rural household panel dataset for 2003 and 2007 applied in the previous chapters. Despite the rich information, the data have not been fully utilized given the lack of pure control groups. Drawing on Townsend’s (1994) risk-sharing model, the empirical results reject the hypothesis of full risk sharing at village level but confirm that risk-sharing functions serve better in securing basic needs such as food. Additionally, in this chapter, I define vulnerability as the lack of ability to smooth consumption because of liquidity constraints caused by restricted access to insurance and/or credit markets. The regression results of risk-sharing models considering the phase-in effects of the three treatment and control groups show that the risk-sharing function, reinforced by longer exposures to the CCT program, serves to mitigate vulnerability of poor households.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The Indian panel data, known as ICRISAT data, is named after the institution that conducted the survey: the International Crops Research Institute for Semi-Arid Tropics.

  2. 2.

    ENCEL 2007 also includes new samples of 18,052 households and 77,768 individuals extracted from the original seven states as well as from some other poor states. They are excluded from the panel data because they are cross-sectional and their profiles are very different from those of ENCEL 2003.

  3. 3.

    The high percentage of the poverty headcount ratio is a result of the ENCEL choosing sample villages from the most marginal rural areas throughout the country. As shown in Chap. 1, the average rural poverty ratios at national level, measured by the same food basket but calculated by per capita income, were 20.0% in 2002, 13.8% in 2006, and 18.4% in 2008 (CONEVAL 2011).

  4. 4.

    Here, I assume that income is exogenous.

  5. 5.

    Other representative empirical studies on risk sharing include Deaton (1992) and Grimard (1997) for Côte d’Ivoire, Udry (1994) for the rural credit market in Nigeria, and Amin et al. (2003) for microfinance in Bangladesh. All of these studies rejected the full risk-sharing hypothesis. See also Bardhan and Udry (1999: Chap. 8) and Kamanou and Morduch (2005) for a detailed literature review on empirical studies on risk sharing.

  6. 6.

    An alternative hypothesis implies a complete autarky or lack of risk-sharing mechanisms.

  7. 7.

    After excluding zero or unreported income and the upper and lower 1% of the sample as outliers, the complete panel data for 2003 and 2007 comprised 12,243 households.

  8. 8.

    Details of the income change for 2001–2002 are explained in Appendix 4.1. The sum of the retrospective wage earnings of household heads and spouses are used as a proxy of lagged household income changes, because data for the newly added control group (Control 2003) are not available for years prior to 2003.

  9. 9.

    Even on regressing models with per capita consumption and income calculated using adult equivalent scales on the basis of Kurosaki (2009) and models without any control variables \(X_{i}\), the results did not change in any of the specifications. The results will be made available upon request.

  10. 10.

    The estimates of three ICRISAT villages conducted by Ravallion and Chaudhuri (1997) range from 0.209 to 0.462 when using flow accounting income data and from 0.120 to 0.336 when using observable transaction income data (Table IV). Kurosaki (2001, Tables 8–6) also produced results similar to those of Ravallion and Chaudhuri (1997) using the same Indian data. In the case of Côte d’Ivoire, the estimated excess sensitivity parameters range from negative (essentially zero) to 0.54. (Deaton 1992, Table 3) In addition, Grimard’s (1997) estimation results using Côte d’Ivoire data are quite robust with coefficients values around 0.2 for different specifications and regression methods.

  11. 11.

    One can infer from the 2SLS regression results that a downward bias caused by measurement errors is greater than other possible biases that can be attributed to specification errors or omitted variables.

  12. 12.

    The coefficient of the tortilla price change was positive but insignificant in OLS estimations and was automatically omitted from 2SLS estimations, as is shown in Table 4.3. Since the price change is an aggregate shock to the whole village, it is possible that the effect is absorbed by the village dummies (see Appendix 4.3 for details).

  13. 13.

    See Fiszbein et al. (2009) for a summary of previous works on CCT evaluations.

  14. 14.

    The full results of the regression will be made available upon request.

References

  • Amin S, Rai AS, Topa G (2003) Does microcredit reach the poor and vulnerable? Evidence from Northern Bangladesh. J Dev Econ 70:59–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angelucci M (2012) Conditional cash transfer programs, credit constraints, and migration. Labor 26(1):124–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angelucci M (2015) Migration and financial constraints: evidence from mexico. Rev Econ Stat 97(1):224–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angelucci M, De Giorgi G (2009) Indirect effects of an aid program: how do cash transfers affect ineligibles’ consumption? Am Econ Rev 99:486–508

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aonuma T (2009) Hinkon Bokumetu Puroguramu ga Imin ni Oyobosu Fukujiteki Koka: Mekishiko Progresa-Oportunidades no Jirei (The secondary effect of a poverty eradication program on migrants: the case of Progresa-oportunidades in Mexico). Latin America Ronshu 43:19–36 (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio O, DiMaro V et al (2009) The welfare consequence of increases in food prices in rural Mexico and Colombia. Mimeograph. http://www.homepages.ucl.ac.uk/~uctpjrt/Files/food%20prices%20mexcol%20d9_2_09.pdf. Accessed on 23 Aug 2013

  • Attanasio O, DiMaro V et al (2013) The welfare consequence of food price increases: evidence from rural Mexico. J Dev Econ 104:136–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan P, Udry C (1999) Development microeconomics. Oxford University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Consejo Nacional de EvaluaciĂłn de la PolĂ­tica de Desarrollo (National Council of the Development Policy Evaluation, CONEVAL) (2011) Nota TĂ©cnica: Instrucciones para consultar del contenido y valor de la canasta básica (Technical notes: instructions for the content and value of the food basket). http://www.coneval.org.mx/Medicion/MP/Paginas/Pobreza_2014.aspx. Accessed on 15 Jan 2013

  • Deaton A (1992) Saving and income smoothing in the CĂ´te d’Ivoire. J Afr Econ 1:1–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dercon S (ed) (2006) Insurance against poverty. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Encuestas de EvaluaciĂłn de los Hogares (Household Evaluation Surveys: ENCEL) 2003 and 2007. https://www.prospera.gob.mx/EVALUACION/es/eval_cuant/bases_cuanti.php. Accessed on 01 July 2012

  • Fiszbein A, Schady N, Ferreira FHG (2009) Conditional cash transfers: reducing present and future poverty. The World Bank, Washington, D.C.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Foster J, Greer J, Thorbecke E (1984) A class of decomposable poverty measures. Econometric 52:761–765

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimard F (1997) Household consumption smoothing through ethnic ties: evidence from CĂ´te d’Ivoire. J Dev Econ 53:391–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamanou G, J Morduch (2005) Measuring vulnerability to poverty. In: Dercon (2005), 155–175

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurosaki T (2001) Kaihatsu no Mikuro Keizaigaku: Riron to Ouyou (Development microeconomics: theory and practice). Iwanami Shoten, Tokyo (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurosaki T (2006) Consumption vulnerability to risk in rural Pakistan. J Dev Stud 42:70–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurosaki T (2009) The economic analysis of poverty and vulnerability. Keiso Shobo, Tokyo (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion M, Chaudhuri S (1997) Risk and Insurance in village India: comment. Econometrica 65:171–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skoufias E (2007) Poverty alleviation and consumption insurance: evidence from PROGRESA in Mexico. J Socio-Econ 36:630–649

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Townsend RM (1994) Risk and insurance in village India. Econometrica J Econometric Soc 62:539–591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Udry C (1994) Risk and insurance in a rural credit market: an empirical investigation in Northern Nigeria. Rev Econ Stud 61:495–526

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Valero-Gil JN, Valero M (2008) The effects of rising food prices on poverty in Mexico. Agric Econ 39:485–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood B, Nelson C, Nogueira L (2009) Food price crisis: welfare impact on mexican households. Paper presented at the International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium (IATRC) Symposium, Seattle, Washington, June 22–23. https://www.researchgate.net/publication/255572075_Food_Price_Crisis_Welfare_Impact_on_Mexican_Households. Accessed on 20 May 2013

  • World Bank (2000) World development report 2000/2001: attacking poverty. Oxford University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Naoko Uchiyama .

Appendices

Appendix 4.1

4.1.1 Variables

  • Household real per capita food consumption: First, I construct each household’s weekly food consumption by summing up the reported amount of weekly food consumption and the estimated weekly self-consumption. Then, I divide the household’s weekly food consumption by the number of household members to ascertain the per capita weekly food consumption. In estimating self-consumption, I first calculate the median state price of each item using each household’s reported weekly purchase and the expenditure on the item. Then, I multiply the value of reported self-consumption by the estimated unit median price of the state. Per capita food consumption is deflated by the annual average food CPI. (Banco de MĂ©xico EstadĂ­sticas: http://www.banxico.org.mx/estadisticas/index.html); June 2001 = 100.

  • Household real per capita total consumption: I construct a household’s real per capita total consumption in the same way as food consumption, using the reported weekly total consumption of food and non-food items. Per capita total consumption is deflated by the annual average general CPI.

  • Household real per capita income in 2003 and 2007: This includes all household members’ wages, pensions, bonuses, monetary institutional transfers (including CCT), agricultural sales, and non-agricultural sales. It excludes personal transfers (including remittances), non-labor or irregular incomes, such as the sales of assets (e.g., houses, cars, and home electronics), inheritance, lottery, gifts, and donations. Personal transfers are excluded because they are more likely to reflect ex post adjustments to shocks, as Skoufias (2007) argues. The reported units for each income source vary from daily, weekly, and monthly to annual. Thus, I estimate the weekly amount of each income source and sum these up to estimate weekly household income. Then, I divide the weekly total income by the number of household members and deflate it by the annual average general CPI. Households that have any type of unreported income sources are dropped from the sample.

  • Household real per capita income in 2001 and 2002: This consists of the sum of the household head and spouse’s retrospective weekly wage income divided by the number of household members, which is deflated by the average annual general CPI.

  • Education dummies: Primary, secondary, or highschool refers to those who have enrolled in a primary, secondary, or high school, regardless of whether they graduated. Technical education refers to those who have enrolled in any technical or vocational school, including teacher’s college. University education includes those who have enrolled for a university and higher education (including those who graduated from university and have entered into or graduated from the post-graduate level).

  • Household demographic variables: The total number of household members refers to the members who live in the same house. It excludes those who live separately for more than one year, whose stay is temporary, and who have expired. The dependency ratio is the proportion of household members under 14 years and over 65 years of age (non-labor force) to the number of household members aged 15–64 years (labor force).

  • Local tortilla price: Drawing on Attanasio et al. (2009, 2013), I first calculate the median village (locality) price of tortilla using each household’s unit price (per kilogram), which is derived by applying the same method used to estimate self-consumption. I exclude median village prices above 20 pesos per kilogram for 2003 and 25 pesos for 2007. Then, I calculate the mean and standard deviation for the remaining median village tortilla prices, which are 4.7 and 2.1 for 2003 and 7.9 and 1.8 for 2007. I use each village’s median price as a local price of tortilla if the median price is between the mean value ± the standard deviation (2.6–6.9 for 2003 and 6.1–9.7 for 2007). The median price of a village with less than three households reporting the purchases of tortilla is also automatically dropped. Local prices that do not meet the criteria are replaced by the corresponding upper level (municipal) median prices, which are calculated using the same method as that for the village median price. I use the state median price as the local tortilla price in case the municipal median prices do not fulfill the criteria mentioned above. Of the sample, 30% was replaced by municipal median prices and 17% by state median prices in 2003, and 24 and 16% of the sample was replaced by municipal and state median prices, respectively, in 2007. The means (weighted by the number of households) of the local tortilla prices are 4.9 pesos per kilogram for 2003 and 8.1 pesos per kilogram for 2007. These estimated prices are quite reasonable since the means of the state median prices (weighted by the number of households) are 5.2 and 8.2 pesos. The local price changes for 2003 and 2007 are deflated by the food CPI.

Appendix 4.2

See Appendix Table 4.7.

Table 4.7 Regression results of the first stage of Eq. (4.12)

Appendix 4.3

See Appendix Tables 4.8 and 4.9.

Table 4.8 Regression results of Eq. (4.12)
Table 4.9 Regression results of Eq. (4.12)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Uchiyama, N. (2017). Household Vulnerability and the CCT Within the Risk-Sharing Framework. In: Household Vulnerability and Conditional Cash Transfers. SpringerBriefs in Economics(). Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-4103-7_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics