Skip to main content

The Theoretical Connection Between John R. Commons and Regulation and Convention Theories

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Contemporary Meanings of John R. Commons’s Institutional Economics

Part of the book series: Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science ((EESCS,volume 5))

Abstract

After discussing the uniqueness of Dewey’s philosophy in relation to (1) the world’s plurality and multiplicity, (2) the primary significance of multifarious interactions, and (3) the interrelation between habit and intelligence, we clarify the uniqueness of Commons’s institutional economics: (1) value theory based on multiple causation; (2) transactions as the ultimate unit of analysis; and (3) the interrelation between habitual assumption and collective action. We examine the theoretical connection between Commons and regulation and convention theories. The former partly shares and develops the first characteristic listed above, multiple causation, while the latter shares and develops the third characteristic, the interrelation between habitual assumption and collective action. In Institutional Economics (Commons, J.R., Institutional economics: Its place in political economy. Macmillan, New York, 1934), applying the idea of “multiple causation,” Commons approached macrodynamics based on the expansion of some key concepts and studies on income distribution and demand growth. This was a prototype of growth analysis based on the cumulative causation model with various forms of coordination, later formulated as regulation theory. Commons, following and developing Dewey’s theory of habit and intelligence, created the concept of “habitual and customary assumptions” and discussed a collective process for achieving “reasonable values,” such as the common-law method. Two-layered coordination in convention theory attempted to explain the psychological means and social mechanisms involved in the persistence of customs and institutions, which Commons briefly mentioned. Using Commons’s theory as a medium, it may be possible to articulate the macrodynamics developed by regulation theory and the micro theory of human interaction developed by convention theory.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Starting from these interactions, Dewey (1927) derived the term “public” and discussed democracy. It is interesting that he called an action with external effects a “transaction.” Moreover, focusing on the spread of the consequences of an action, he distinguished two kinds of consequences: “those which affect the persons directly engaged in a transaction, and those which affect others beyond those immediately concerned.” He found in this distinction “the germ of the distinction between the private and the public” (Dewey 1927, pp.12–13).

  2. 2.

    As 1–(1/1.75) = 0.4286, the passage “the prices of clothing been reduced 33 per cent” should be replaced by “the prices of clothing been reduced 43 per cent.”

  3. 3.

    Boyer’s model is based in the ideas of Myrdal (1957) and Kaldor (1966). According to Kapp (2011), the principle of cumulative causation is at the core of institutional economics and sets it apart from earlier and contemporary noninstitutional approaches, in particular the mechanistic equilibrium approach.

  4. 4.

    The original text is in French, so all quoted sentences hereafter are author translations.

  5. 5.

    Kitagawa (2016) refuted the criticism by Hodgson (2003) from the perspective of instrumental pragmatism.

  6. 6.

    Almost identical explanations are found in the 1927 manuscript (Commons 1927, Chapter 4, s.23). Compared with Chapter 4 in the 1927 manuscript, the major revisions in Chapter 4 in Institutional Economics are as follows. The text emphasizing the difference between habit and custom in Institutional Economics (Commons, 1934, pp.152–153) did not exist in the 1927 manuscript. The title of Section 2 of Chapter 4 in Institutional Economics is “From Habit to Custom,” but in the 1927 manuscript, it is “Custom.” The text referring to the habitual assumption (Commons 1934, p.156) did not exist in the 1927 manuscript, and Sect. 4 did not exist in the 1927 manuscript.

  7. 7.

    Based on the first sentence of this quotation, we infer that “institutional idea of reason” is a typographical error.

  8. 8.

    The following should be noted: the convention, as it is defined by conventionists, is a kind of structure that formalizes the individual comportments in collective action. Batifoulier and De Larquier state that “the main point is that there is no predetermined or conventional formation of convention. This comes from the fact that rules work as a convention because the rules have lost their origin” (Batifoulier and De Larquier 2001, pp.11–12). For that matter, the term “convention” appears only twice in Commons’s Institutional Economics (Commons 1934, p.26 and p.249) and is used to explain the work of other scholars. However, the understanding by convention theory that conventions are rules that have lost their origin is similar to the understanding by Commons of habitual assumptions, as noted in Sect. 4.1.

References

  • Basle, M. 2002. Acknowledged and Unacknowledged Institutionalist Antecedents of Regulation Theory. In Régulation Theory: The State of the Art, ed. R. Boyer and Y. Saillard. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Batifoulier, P., ed. 2001. Théorie des Conventions. Paris: Economica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Batifoulier, P., and G. De Larquier 2001. De la convention et de ses usages (On the Convention and Its Usages). In Batifoulier (ed.) (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  • Batifoulier, P., and O. Thévenon 2001. Interprétation et fondement conventionnel des règles (Interpretation and Conventional Foundation of the Rules). In Batifoulier (ed.) (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  • Bessy, C., and O. Favereau 2003. Institutions et Économie des Conventions. Cahiers d’ Économie Politique (Institutions and Economics of the Conventions. Papers in Political Economy) 44: 119–164.

    Google Scholar 

  • Biencourt, C., C. Chaserrant, and A. Rebérioux 2001. L’État des conventions: l’affirmation d’un programme de recherche (The States of the Conventions: Affirmation of a Research Program). In Batifoulier (ed.) (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  • Boisvert, R.D. 1998. John Dewey: Rethinking Our Time. New York: State University of New York Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boltanski, L., and E. Chiapello 1999. Le Nouvel Esprit du Capitalisme. Paris: Editions Gallimard. (The New Spirit of Capitalism). Translated by Gregory Elliot. 2005. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boltanski, L., and L. Thévenot. 1991. De la Justification: Les Économies de la Grandeur (On Justification: Economies of Worth). Paris: Editions Gallimard.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S. 2004. Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boyer, R. 1988. Formalizing Growth Regimes. In Technical Change and Economic Theory, ed. G. Dosi et al. London: Pinter Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2002. Is Régulation Theory an Original Theory of Economic Institutions? In Régulation Theory: The State of the Art, ed. R. Boyer and Y. Saillard. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2004a. Théorie de la Régulation, 1. Les Fondamentaux (Regulation Theory, Vol. 1. The Fundamentals). Paris: Éditions La Découverte.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2004b. Une Théorie du Capitalism est-ell Possible? (Is a Theory of Capitalism Possible?). Paris: Odile Jacob.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaserant, C., and O. Thévenot 2001. Aux origines de la théorie économique des conventions : prix, règles et représentations (On the Origins of the Economic Theory of Conventions: Price, Rules and Representations). In Batifoulier (ed.) (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  • Commons, J. R. 1927. Reasonable Value: A Theory of Volitional Economics. Manuscript. Collection of the Kyoto Prefectural Library. Call mark: /331.04/C85/, Material code: 1102508007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Commons, J.R. 1934. Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewey, J. 1910. A Short Catechism Concerning Truth. In The Influence of Darwinism on Philosophy and Other Essays, ed. Dewey J. New York: Henry Holt & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1917. The Need for the Recovery of Philosophy. In Creative Intelligence: Essays in the Pragmatic Attitude, ed. J. Dewey. New York: Henry Holt & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1922. Human Nature and Conduct: An Introduction to Social Psychology. New York: Henry Holt & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1927. The Public and Its Problems. New York: Henry Holt & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., and K.M. Schmidt. 1999. Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(3): 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G.M. 2003. John R. Commons and the Foundations of the Institutional Economics. Journal of Economic Issues 37(3): 547–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, N. 1966. Causes of the Slow Growth in the United Kingdom. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. (Republished in Kaldor, N., Further Essays on Economic Theory. London: Duckworth, 1978).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kapp, K. W. 2011. The Foundations of Institutional Economics, ed. S. Berger and R. Steppacher. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kitagawa, K. 2016. Cumulative Causation in J.R. Commons’s Institutional Economics from the Perspective of Instrumental Pragmatism. Cahiers d’économie politique (Papers in Political Economy) 70: 75–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myrdal, G. 1957. Economic Theory and Under-developed Regions. London: Gerald Duckworth.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petit, P. 2005. Croissance et Richesse des Nations (Growth and Wealth of Nations). Paris: La Découverte (coll. Repères).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rebérioux, A., Biencourt, O., and P. Gabriel 2001. La dynamique des conventions entre consensus et conflit (The dynamics of the conventions between consensus and conflict). In Batifoulier (ed.) (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford, M. 1994. Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism. In Cambridge. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tokumaru, N. 2016. Social Preference, Institution, and Distribution: An Experimental and Philosophical Approach. Singapore: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Uni, H. 2007. Growth Regimes in Japan and the United States in the 1990s. Revue de la régulation 1: 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2017. Scope of John R. Commons’s Criticism on the Classical Theory of Value: Progress and Limits. In the 1927 Manuscript. In Contemporary Meanings of John R. Commons’s Institutional Economics: An Analysis Using a Newly Discovered Manuscript, ed. H. Uni. Singapore: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This work was supported by the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (JSPS), the KAKENHI Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research (B) (grant number 26285048).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hiroyuki Uni .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Uni, H., Nakahara, T. (2017). The Theoretical Connection Between John R. Commons and Regulation and Convention Theories. In: Uni, H. (eds) Contemporary Meanings of John R. Commons’s Institutional Economics. Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science, vol 5. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-3202-8_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-3202-8_7

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-3201-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-3202-8

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics