Skip to main content

An Overview of Research into International Values in Japan

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
A New Construction of Ricardian Theory of International Values

Part of the book series: Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science ((EESCS,volume 7))

Abstract

In Japan, research into international values has been conducted vigorously since the latter half of the 1940s. From a global perspective, studies that emphasize demand factors in the determination of international values have been dominant; however, this has not been the case in Japan. Neoclassical studies of this subject have not been as vitalized. Rather, many of the studies have succeeded the works of Ricardo, Marx, Graham, and Sraffa who placed a high priority on supply factors in the determination of commodity prices. Research on this topic is divided roughly into two periods owing to its contents and characteristics. One is the period until the 1980s and the other is that since the 1990s. Research in the first period was chiefly carried out by Marxian economists, and that in the second period, based on Graham and Sraffa, has led to the birth of the new theory of international values developed in this book. In this chapter, we provide an overview of research into international values in Japan. In addition, we explain Graham’s relatively unknown theory of international values and show the fundamental structure of the Graham-type model (a modified version of Graham’s original model and a multi-country multi-commodity Ricardian trade model). Furthermore, we present a way in which to derive an equilibrium solution of this model practically.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Marx (1887, p. 396). The following quotations from Marx are on the same page.

  2. 2.

    See Kinoshita (1960) and Naruse (1985) about the outline of the argument.

  3. 3.

    Although most researchers did not give a quantitative definition of national productivity differentials, a number of them, we think, adopted the second standpoint, as Japanese Marxian economists believed that demand was never involved in the determination of values. Exceptionally, Kihara (1986) adopted the first standpoint and Yukizawa (1957) the third.

  4. 4.

    There was criticism of the theory by Marxian economists. Sasaki (1989) pointed out that it was fundamentally impossible to average the productivity differentials of different sectors, while Motoyama (1982) wrote that we could never know the productivity level of the car industry in developing countries.

  5. 5.

    See Muraoka (1968) and Sasaki (1998).

  6. 6.

    See Negishi (1982, p. 202).

  7. 7.

    Although Negishi (1982) did not exclude the case in which one country produces two commodities, we omit it here to explain the case.

  8. 8.

    His related works are Graham (1923, 1932, 1948). The following explanation mainly relies on Graham (1948).

  9. 9.

    McKenzie (1954a) presented a mathematical treatment for Graham’s model, and McKenzie (1954b) tried to prove the existence and uniqueness of the equilibrium solutions in the model. Shiozawa (2014), however, indicated that the proof was wrong because the demand functions assumed by McKenzie were different from Graham’s (p. 290).

  10. 10.

    See von Mangoldt (1975).

  11. 11.

    See Section 4, Chapter 8 of Viner (1937).

  12. 12.

    Graham refers to the case of variable opportunity costs too and indicates that the number of commodities produced in common in more than one country would grow under the increasing opportunity costs (Graham 1948, pp. 146–151).

  13. 13.

    Graham is not indifferent to the problem. For example, he writes that national prosperity (per capita income or wage rate) is a function of two variables, per capita physical productivity and the terms of trade, and the former is more important (ibid., p. 50, pp. 212–213, p. 233). He also refers to money wages (ibid., p. 261, p. 307).

  14. 14.

    Kojima (1949) and Minabe (1956) were critical. Noguchi (1987) introduced the two-country two-commodity case affirmatively.

  15. 15.

    About this research stream, see Sect. 2, Chapter “Analysis of Production Efficient Patterns of Specialization Allowing Intermediate Inputs: The Meaning of Shiozawa's Model with a Viewpoint of Modern Economics” of this book.

  16. 16.

    See Sect. 4 for the reason.

  17. 17.

    See Shiozawa (2014, p. 372). If M and N are large, it is very difficult even to identify the reasonable patterns. Including the rest of the process, the support of computer program would be needed in order to calculate actually.

  18. 18.

    Although the number of conditions (therefore, equations) is N, one is invalid owing to Walras’ law.

  19. 19.

    The number of the reasonable patterns is ∑(M + N − l − 2)!/{(M − l − 1)!(N − l − 1)!l!}(l = 1, 2, …, M − 1), where l is the number of disconnections (suggested by the description of Shiozawa, 2012, p. 50).

  20. 20.

    The probability that the existence of trade in intermediate goods brings about losses from trade is not zero but very small. On the contrary, the possibility for the existence to yield extended gains from trade is very large. (See McKenzie (1954a), Evans (1989), and Samuelson (2001).)

  21. 21.

    However, his numerical example to show the invalidity of the theorems was in fact wrong, since the example did not satisfy the condition that there is no factor intensity reversal. Kurose and Yoshihara (2016) indicate this and give a correct example to show the invalidity of the theorems.

References

  • Evans, H. D. (1989). Comparative advantage and growth: Trade and development in theory and practice. New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Golub, S. S., & Hsieh, C.-T. (2000). Classical Ricardian theory of comparative advantage revisited. Review of International Economics, 8(2), 221–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham, F. D. (1923). The theory of international values re-examined. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 38(1), 54–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham, F. D. (1932). The theory of international values. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 46(4), 581–616.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham, F. D. (1948). The theory of international values. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R. W. (1961). Comparative advantage and the theory of tariffs: A multi-country, multi-commodity model. Review of Economic Studies, 28(3), 161–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kihara Y. (1986). Essence of the surplus profits obtained by Export (19), Tokyokeidai GakkaiShi (Tokyo Keizai University), 147, 217–258 (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kinoshita, E. (Ed.). (1960). Readings in the theory of international values. Tokyo: Kobundo (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kojima, K. (1949). Graham’s theory of international values. Hitotsubashi Ronso, 22(4), 579–589 (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kojima, K. (1951). Ricardo’s theory of international balance of payments equilibrium. Annals of the Hitotsubashi Academy, 2(1), 76–92. (Reprinted in Trade, investment and Pacific economic integration: Selected essays of Kiyoshi Kojima. Tokyo: Bunshindo, 1996).

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. R., Obstfeld, M., & Melitz, M. J. (2015). International economics: Theory and policy (10th ed.). Boston: Pearson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurose, K., & Yoshihara, N. (2016). The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson model and the Cambridge capital controversies (TERG Discussion Papers, 346). Online: http://www.econ.tohoku.ac.jp/e-dbase/dp/terg.html

  • Marx, K. (1887) Capital: A critique of political economy (Vol. I), English edition of “Das Kapital”. Online: http://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1867-c1/index.htm

  • McKenzie, L. (1954a). Specialisation and efficiency in world production. Review of Economic Studies, 21(3), 165–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie, L. (1954b). On equilibrium in Graham’s model of world trade and other competitive systems. Econometrica, 22(2), 147–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mill, J. S. (1848). Principles of political economy: With some of their applications to social philosophy. New York: John W. Parker.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minabe, N. (1956). International values and gains from foreign trade. Keizaigaku Zasshi (Osaka City University), 34(1/2), 41–75 (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Motoyama, Y. (1982). Toward a trade theory. Tokyo: Yuhikaku (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Muraoka, S. (1968). Toward a theory of capital export. Kenkyu-nenpo Keizaigaku (Tohoku University), 29(3/4), 51–61 (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Naruse, S. (1985). On the argument over International values. In Kinoshita, & Muraoka (Eds.), State, international trade and world market. Tokyo: Yuhikaku (in Japanese)

    Google Scholar 

  • Nawa, T. (1949) Studies in the theory of international values. Tokyo: Nippon Hyoron Sha (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Negishi, T. (1982), The labor theory of value in the Ricardian theory of international trade. History of Political Economy, 14(2), 199–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Negishi, T. (1996). Japanese studies on Ricardo’s theory of foreign trade. Japanese Economic Review, 47(4), 335–345.

    Google Scholar 

  • Noguchi, A. (1987) Graham’s critique of the classical theory of international trade. Keizaigaku Ronsyu (University of Tokyo), 53(2), 25–44 (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo, D. (1817). On the principles of political economy and taxation. Edited by Piero Sraffa with the collaboration of M. H. Dobb, The works and correspondence of David Ricardo, vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1951.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (2001). A Ricardo-Sraffa paradigm comparing gains from trade in inputs and finished goods. Journal of Economic Literature, 39(4), 1204–1214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sasaki, T. (1989). Toward a theory of international values. Keizaigaku Kenkyu (Hokkaido University), 39(2), 40–59 (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Sasaki, T. (1998). International division of labour and capital export in a Ricardian model. Economic Journal of Hokkaido University, 27, 1–9. The Japanese article with the approximately same content was published in Keizaigaku Kenkyu (Hokkaido University), 41(3), 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, H. (1990). F. D. Graham’s theory of international values. Artes Liberales (Iwate University), 46, 163–191 (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, H. (1994). The principles of international division of labor and foreign trade. Tokyo: Sohusya (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Sato, H. (2016). New development in Graham-type theory of international values (TERG Discussion Papers, 343). Online: http://www.econ.tohoku.ac.jp/e-dbase/dp/terg.html (in Japanese).

  • Shiozawa, Y. (2007). A new construction of Ricardian trade theory: A many-country, many-commodity case with intermediate goods and choice of production techniques. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, 3(2), 141–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shiozawa, Y. (2012). Subtropical convex geometry as the Ricardian theory of international trade. Discussion Paper uploaded in Shiozawa’s Contribution page in ResearchGate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiozawa, Y. (2014). A final solution of Ricardo problem on international values. Tokyo: Iwanami Shoten (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. (1960). Production of commodities by means of commodities; Prelude to a critique of economic theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steedman, I. (Ed.). (1979) Fundamental issues in trade theory. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Takamasu, A. (1991). Neo-Ricardian trade theory. Tokyo: Sobunsha (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Trefler, D. (1995). The case of the missing trade and other mysteries. American Economic Review, 85(5), 1029–1046.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viner, J. (1937). Studies in the theory of international trade. New York: Harper & Brothers.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mangoldt, H. (1975). On the equation of international demand. Journal of International Economics, 5(1), 55–97. The German original was published in 1863 and the translation from German was carried out by Siegfried Schach and was edited by J. S. Chipman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yukizawa, K. (1957). Toward an international economics. Kyoto: Minerva Shobo (in Japanese).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgment

We would like to thank Kazuhiro Kurose for his useful suggestions and helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hideo Sato .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Science+Business Media Singapore

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Sato, H. (2017). An Overview of Research into International Values in Japan. In: Shiozawa, Y., Oka, T., Tabuchi, T. (eds) A New Construction of Ricardian Theory of International Values. Evolutionary Economics and Social Complexity Science, vol 7. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-0191-8_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics