Skip to main content

Economic Evaluation of Implementing Minimum Legal Size on Blue Swimming Crab Fishery in Indonesia

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Marine and Coastal Ecosystem Valuation, Institutions, and Policy in Southeast Asia
  • 882 Accesses

Abstract

The blue swimming crab (BSC) or rajungan is one of the most valuable fish products in Indonesia. It is mostly caught by using bottom gillnets and collapsible traps and by using – to a lesser extent – the now-illegal shallow bottom trawls (baby trawls or mini trawls). Based on recent catch reports, there are indications that the average size of the landed BSC is becoming smaller (as indicated in the increase in catching effort). There are also signs that BSC is no longer producing maximum economic benefits in some regions of Indonesia. In many landing areas, even small crabs (150 crabs/kg) are being caught and harvested. In order to keep its sustainability, it is important to regulate the size of crabs to be caught by fishers. Some management options have already been established, including catch restrictions on the minimum legal size of 8 cm.

This study used a bioeconomic model to assess and compare the consequences of unrestricted fishery (no regulation) and implementation of minimum legal size on the stock condition of BSC. The study determined how much the profit loss would be due to the smaller-sized crab catch and due to the decline in fish catch (overfishing) and how much the implementation of a minimum legal size will change the productivity and income of fishermen over time. The effect of this restriction policy was evaluated using cost-benefit analysis. In the considerably depleted area, the projection showed that implementing a minimum legal size (MLS) policy would increase the stock of BSC in the early years of the projection. The model also showed that for the next 10 years, crab stock with size bigger than 8.5 cm would increase in the early years of the projection and then achieve a stable condition in the following years. Thus, MLS policy can help crab stocks to recover. Meanwhile, in the area where stock condition is considerably good, the crab stock would stay stable in the next 10 years. From the profitability point of view, MLS would benefit those fishermen who catch the mature BSC. Likewise, implementing such policy would also benefit the miniplant industry (BSC-processing business) in the long run (assuming a 10-year period). However, their income would be slightly affected in the short term.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Export value is using unit price based on foreign trade data provided by NMFS http://www.st.nmfs.noaa.gov/st1/trade/index.html

  2. 2.

    See www.committedtocrab.org for information about the NFI Crab Council and its commitments to promoting sustainable fish harvests in Indonesia and other countries.

  3. 3.

    The APRI was formed in 2007.

  4. 4.

    At the time of writing, the exchange rate was 1 US dollar equals IDR 9000.

  5. 5.

    In Table 17.2, harvest data for 2005 are missing, not zero.

    Table 17.2 Crabmeat yield and labor cost by crab size
  6. 6.

    Foreign matter and other contaminants may also affect the quality of the crabmeat.

  7. 7.

    The estimation is based on a variant to the Gordon-Schaefer model and follows the procedures developed in Hilborn (1976) for the unregulated fishery and Anna (2003) for the fishery with a minimum size regulation.

  8. 8.

    The parameter k could also change if fishers increase their fishing effort by extending their fishing grounds. In the estimation for BSC done in this paper, the catchability coefficient, q, was constant, producing different levels of production with and without the minimum size regulation. Thus the carrying capacities (K) are different between the two scenarios. These conditions need to be tested again in a more robust model and after the minimum size has been implemented and enforced.

  9. 9.

    There are a number of different ways to standardize effort estimates ranging in complexity. Due to data limitations, the approach taken here aggregates the number of trips using the most prevalent gear in the fishery (gillnets) plus trips using other gear.

  10. 10.

    A more robust model and longer data series to estimate parameters may lead to greater differences in a simulation with and without size regulation.

  11. 11.

    Minimum size regulation would therefore help enforce bans on the use of mini trawls. They may still be used however for fishers selling their crabs locally or for household consumption.

  12. 12.

    Data on fishing costs, incomes, and NPV from shrimp fishing in Belitung are available from the authors.

  13. 13.

    Some collapsible traps are used in Belitung. Only 1 % of crabs harvested using traps were found to be less than 8 cm carapace.

  14. 14.

    Data for miniplant costs comes from interviews with plant owners.

  15. 15.

    The impact on crab stocks, fishing effort, and harvests for Cirebon Regency was simulated using Vensim software. After a one-period decline in stocks and harvest, stocks rebound and harvests and effort increase. Details of the simulation can be obtained from the authors.

  16. 16.

    The internal rate of return to investment in a miniplant in Belitung Regency is 37 %.

References

  • Anna S (2003) Model embedded: interactive economic dynamics of fisheries and pollution. Dissertation of Post Graduate. Bogor Agricultural University

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilborn R (1976) Optimal exploitation of multiple stocks by a common fishery. Can J Fish Res Board Can 33:1–5

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MMAF (Ministry of Marine Affairs and Fisheries), JICA (Japan International Cooperation Agency) (2009) Indonesian fisheries statistics index. Jakarta

    Google Scholar 

  • Sutinen J (1999) What works well and why: evidence from fishery-management experiences in OECD countries. ICES J Mar Sci 56:1051–1058

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rizal Bahtiar .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer Science+Business Media Singapore

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Bahtiar, R., Nuva, Anggraeni, D., Hidayat, N.K. (2016). Economic Evaluation of Implementing Minimum Legal Size on Blue Swimming Crab Fishery in Indonesia. In: Olewiler, N., Francisco, H., Ferrer, A. (eds) Marine and Coastal Ecosystem Valuation, Institutions, and Policy in Southeast Asia. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-0141-3_17

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-0141-3_17

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-0139-0

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-0141-3

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics