Skip to main content

Emigration, Immigration, and Skill Formation: The Case of a Midstream Country

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Economics of International Immigration

Part of the book series: New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives ((NFRSASIPER,volume 27))

Abstract

The word “international migration” usually refers to labor inflows for highly developed countries (HDCs) such as Germany, Japan, and the United States. For lower developed countries (LDCs) such as Bangladesh, Cambodia, and most African countries, migration implies an outflow of labor. Most of the economic literature has focused on mutual relationships between the source and host countries and studied the effects of international migration on the economies of those countries. However, globalization in the more recent past has resulted in several new types of international migration. In observing the recent expansion of multilateral economic integration between countries at various phases of development, we recognize that several medium-developed countries (MDCs) are playing a new role in the international labor market. These MDCs export labor to HDCs and, simultaneously, import labor from LDCs. In other words, these countries are coincidentally host as well as source countries and are at the midstream of international labor flows.

This paper was originally published by International Journal of Population Research, in 2014 (ID: 858460).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Hamberger (2010) for detailed information about the present situation of migration in Romania.

  2. 2.

    Following World Bank data, remittances sent home by Romanians abroad flat at USD 3.6 bln in 2013.

  3. 3.

    See Fujita et al. (2010) and Yamada (2012) for detailed information on labor inflow and outflow in Thailand.

  4. 4.

    Yamada (2012) surveys the backgrounds and transition of immigration policies of Thailand. Fujita et al. (2010) shed light on the actual working conditions and life of Myanmar migrants in Thailand, based on an intensive survey in Ranong in Southern Thailand in 2009.

  5. 5.

    Concerning with the current situation about Mexican labor market, see Mariel (2011), for example.

  6. 6.

    See Webb (1970), Bhagwati (1979), Calvo and Wellisz (1983), Bhagwati and Srinivasan (1983), Ruffin (1984), Jones and Coelho (1985), Jones et al. (1986), Kuhn and Wooton (1987), and Jones and Easton (1989).

  7. 7.

    This specified production function has a quite convenient property that marginal product of labor is the linear decreasing function of labor input. This property is assumed by MacDougall (1960), and most of the extension studies of this study adopt this assumption.

  8. 8.

    We assume the number of domestic skilled workers in country A’s industrial sector is not sufficient and the marginal products of labor is higher than \( {\overline{w}}_A^S \). Then for this sector, it is possible to enlarge total outputs and GDP by introducing some skilled workers from country B, L S AB , until the marginal products of labor are equal with \( {\overline{w}}_A^S \). Thus, legal migration of skilled workers is just to satisfy this shortage of workers. Another story is that immigration policy of country A is quota and introduces a fixed number of skilled workers from less developed countries. By the existence of social policy like livelihood protection system, we assume those migrants’ expected income is not less than a crucial standard.

  9. 9.

    We introduce migration cost following Miyagiwa (1991) and Contreras (2013).

  10. 10.

    Djajić and Michael (2009, 2013), respectively, studied the political interactions between the host and the source countries in the case of temporary workers and skilled workers’ migration. In addition, Djajić et al. (2012) studied similar subjects under the guest worker system. To simplify our study, we consider only that the host country can introduce some restriction policies.

  11. 11.

    National income of country B is just equal with the sum of domestic skilled workers’ income (including both emigrants and those left behind) and domestic unskilled workers’ income. As we focus on the nationality, regardless of the existing fraction of immigrants settled in their new homeland, immigrants’ income is not included. In this study, as the number of emigrants and their wage rates are exogenously given, the government intends to maximize the sum of domestic unskilled workers’ income, area OKDR, and remaining skilled workers’ income, area GLA. Therefore, in reality, area OGEDR does not include emigrants’ income; in this study, we call this national income for convenience. We need to remark that the GDP of country B equals with area OGEN, while unskilled immigrants’ income is area RDEN.

    We need to remark that in Case 1, L U BC denotes the number of immigrants from C to B, while in Case 2, it denotes aggregate illegal immigrants including both succeeded and failed. The number of existing illegal workers is \( \left(1-\rho \right){L}_{BC}^U. \)

  12. 12.

    This model can be interpreted for legal migration where the government can maximize national income by imposing income tax on the wage of unskilled immigrants optimally.

  13. 13.

    Another scenario of country B is optimal restriction of skilled emigration. Similar analysis can be done considering optimally controlled tax rate imposed on the income of emigrants.

  14. 14.

    From (13.6) and (13.10), we can conclude that there are no unskilled immigrants, L U BC , in the case that \( {L}_B^S={\tilde{L}}_B^S\equiv \left(-{a}^{\prime }{\overline{L}}_C^U+{T}_C+a{L}_B\right)/\left(1-p+a\right) \). We consider certain value of parameters \( {\overline{w}}_A^S, \mu, \tau \), and γ 1 which guarantees that the number of skilled domestic workers L S B which satisfies (13.5) without unskilled immigrants is larger than \( {\tilde{L}}_B^S \). In this case, we obtain two equilibrium points, E 1 and E 2, of two respective cases.

  15. 15.

    If p that is determined by (13.5) satisfies \( p>1-\frac{a-{\lambda}_i}{1+b} \), which implies \( d{L}_{BC}^U/d{L}_B^S<2 \), \( d\left[{L}_B^U+{L}_{BC}^U\right]/d{L}_B^S \) is positive in sign, and it could be smaller than unit. As from (13.2), we have \( d{w}_B^S=\left(d{L}_B^U+d{L}_{BC}^U\right)-bd{L}_B^S=\left[\frac{d\left({L}_B^U+{L}_{BC}^U\right)}{d{L}_B^S}-b\right]d{L}_B^S \) and \( d{w}_B^U=d{L}_B^S-a\left(d{L}_B^U+d{L}_{BC}^U\right)=\left[1-a\frac{d\left({L}_B^U+{L}_{BC}^U\right)}{d{L}_B^S}\right]d{L}_B^S \), remembering that after restriction \( d{L}_B^S<0 \), we can conclude that \( d{w}_B^S>0 \) if \( d\left[{L}_B^U+{L}_{BC}^U\right]/d{L}_B^S<b \) and \( d{w}_B^U<0 \) if \( d\left[{L}_B^U+{L}_{BC}^U\right]/d{L}_B^S<1/a \).

  16. 16.

    Parameter a denotes the marginal change of marginal products of unskilled labor in country B, and in reality, it seems not constant and not so large in midstream countries like Thailand. As we specify the production function as (13.2), parameter a is independent of skill formation, the ratio of skilled/unskilled domestic labor. This simplified assumption is strong, but it shows the existence of a counterintuitive result clearly which should be possible under more general production function case.

References

  • Bhagwati, J. (1979). International factor movements and national advantage. Indian Economic Review, 14, 73–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J. N., & Sirinivasan, T. N. (1983). On the choice between capital and labor mobility. Journal of International Economics, 14, 209–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G., & Wellisz, S. (1983). International factor mobility and national advantage. Journal of International Economics, 14, 103–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chao, C. C., & Yu, E. S. H. (2002). Immigration and welfare for the host economy with imperfect competition. Journal of Regional Science, 42, 327–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coniglio, N. D., & Kondoh, K. (2015). International integration with heterogeneous immigration policies. International Economics, 142, 15–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Contreras, S. (2013). The influence of migration on human capital development. International Economic Journal, 27, 365–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djajić, S. (1989). Skills and the pattern of migration: The role of qualitative and quantitative restrictions on international labor mobility. International Economic Review, 30, 795–809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djajić, S., & Michael, M. S. (2009). Temporary migration policies and welfare of the host and source countries: A game–theoretic approach. CESifo Working Paper Series No. 2811.

    Google Scholar 

  • Djajić, S., & Michael, M. S. (2013). Guest worker programs: A theoretical analysis of welfare of the host and source countries. Journal of International Trade and Economic Development, 22, 454–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djajić, S., Michael, M. S., & Vinogradova, A. (2012). Migration of skilled workers: Policy interaction between host and source countries. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 1015–1024.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, K., Endo, T., Okamoto, I., Nakanishi, Y., & Yamada, M. (2010). Myanmar migrant labors in Ranong, Thailand. Discussion Paper Series No. 257, Institute of Developing Economies (IDE), JETRO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamberger, A. (2010). Immigration and the integration of immigrants in Romania. Migrationonline.cz: 7 pages.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R. W., & Coelho, I. (1985). International factor movements and the Ramaswami argument. Economica, 52, 359–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R. W., & Easton, S. T. (1989). Perspectives on ‘buy-out’ and the Ramaswami effect. Journal of International Economics, 27, 363–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R. W., Coelho, I., & Easton, S. T. (1986). The theory of international factor flows: The basic model. Journal of International Economics, 20, 313–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kondoh, K. (2000). Legal migration and illegal migration: The effectiveness of qualitative and quantitative restriction policies. Journal of International Trade and Economic Development, 9, 227–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn, P., & Wooton, I. (1987). International factor movements in the presence of a fixed factor. Journal of International Economics, 22, 123–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacDougall, G. D. A. (1960). The benefits and costs of private investment from abroad: A theoretical approach. Economic Record, 26, 13–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mariel, M. N. (2011, Lecture). Mexican diaspola. Institute of Global Studies, Doshisha University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miyagiwa, K. (1991). Scale economies in education and the brain drain problem. International Economic Review, 32, 743–759.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramaswami, V. K. (1969). International factor movement and the national advantage. Economica, 35, 309–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruffin, R. J. (1984). International factor movements. In R. W. Jones & P. Kenen (Eds.), Handbook of international economics (Vol. 1). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Webb, R. L. (1970). International factor movement and the national advantage, a comment. Economica, 37, 81–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamada, M. (2012, in Japanese) Current trends and issues of immigration policies in Thailand. In M. Yamada (Eds.), Higashi Asia ni okeru Hito no Idou no Houseido [Law and migration policies in East Asia]. Chapter 4 of Interim Report FY 2011–2012 Research Topic 1–08, Institute of Developing Economies (IDE), JETRO.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

The detailed calculations of the comparative statics are as follows:

$$ {\Delta}_1\frac{d{L}_B^S}{d\mu }=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} 1 & \Phi \\ {} 0 & -a-{a}^{\prime} \end{array}\right|=-\left(a+{a}^{\prime}\right)<0, $$
$$ {\Delta}_1\frac{d{L}_{BC}^U}{d\mu }=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} \Psi & 1 \\ {} 1-p+a & 0 \end{array}\right|=-\left(1-p+a\right)<0, $$
$$ {\Delta}_1\frac{d{L}_B^S}{d{\overline{w}}_A^S}=-{\Delta}_1\frac{d{L}_B^S}{d{\gamma}_1}=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} -p & \Phi \\ {} 0 & -a-{a}^{\prime} \end{array}\right|=p\left(a+{a}^{\prime}\right)>0, $$
$$ {\Delta}_1\frac{d{L}_{BC}^U}{d{\overline{w}}_A^S}=-{\Delta}_1\frac{d{L}_{BC}^U}{d{\gamma}_1}=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} \Psi & -p \\ {} 1-p+a & 0 \end{array}\right|=p\left(1-p+a\right)>0, $$
$$ {\Delta}_1\frac{d{L}_B^S}{d\tau }=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} -W & \Phi \\ {} 0 & -a-{a}^{\prime} \end{array}\right|=W\left(a+{a}^{\prime}\right)>0, $$
$$ {\Delta}_1\frac{d{L}_{BC}^U}{d\tau }=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} \Psi & -W \\ {} 1-p+a & 0 \end{array}\right|=W\left(1-p+a\right)>0, $$
$$ {\Delta}_2\frac{d{L}_B^S}{d\mu }=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} 1 & \Phi \\ {} 0 & -a-2{a}^{\prime} \end{array}\right|=-\left(a+2{a}^{\prime}\right)<0, $$
$$ {\Delta}_2\frac{d{L}_{BC}^U}{d\mu }=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} \Psi & 1 \\ {} 1-p+a & 0 \end{array}\right|=-\left(1-p+a\right)<0, $$
$$ {\Delta}_2\frac{d{L}_B^S}{d{\overline{w}}_A^S}=-{\Delta}_2\frac{d{L}_B^S}{d{\gamma}_1}=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} -p & \Phi \\ {} 0 & -a-2{a}^{\prime} \end{array}\right|=p\left(a+2{a}^{\prime}\right)>0, $$
$$ {\Delta}_2\frac{d{L}_{BC}^U}{d{\overline{w}}_A^S}=-{\Delta}_2\frac{d{L}_{BC}^U}{d{\gamma}_1}=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} \Psi & -p \\ {} 1-p+a & 0 \end{array}\right|=p\left(1-p+a\right)>0, $$
$$ \displaystyle {\Delta}_2\frac{d{L}_B^S}{d\tau }=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} -W & \Phi \\ {} 0 & -a-2{a}^{\prime} \end{array}\right|=W\left(a+2{a}^{\prime}\right)>0, $$
$$ {\Delta}_2\frac{d{L}_{BC}^U}{d\tau }=\left|\arraycolsep6pt\begin{array}{cc} \Psi & -W \\ {} 1-p+a & 0 \end{array}\right|=W\left(1-p+a\right)>0. $$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer Science+Business Media Singapore

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kondoh, K. (2017). Emigration, Immigration, and Skill Formation: The Case of a Midstream Country. In: The Economics of International Immigration. New Frontiers in Regional Science: Asian Perspectives, vol 27. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-0092-8_13

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-0092-8_13

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-0091-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-0092-8

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics