Skip to main content

Time is Economically Valuable: Production, Consumption and Transfers of Time by Age and Sex

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 345 Accesses

Part of the book series: SpringerBriefs in Population Studies ((BRIEFSPOPULAT))

Abstract

This chapter presents the core of our analysis. Here we discuss our methods and map time transfers between generations and genders. First, we summarize and discuss the existing literature on unpaid family work, non-monetary transfers, and the economic value of time. Second, we describe national Time Use Surveys and harmonized Time Use studies available for the selected countries. Hence, we discuss criteria to assess the economic value of time spent in different activities and use these criteria to identify a set of unpaid activities, in order to define “household production”. Third, we describe and discuss the methods that we developed to estimate time production, consumption, and transfers by age and gender. While time production can be estimated directly from time use surveys, an indirect approach is needed to evaluate profiles of time consumption. Finally, we present our estimates of the life cycle deficits: the differences over the life course in per-capita profiles of household production and consumption, across countries. We observe large gender differences in household production. Profiles are qualitatively similar across countries, but there are relevant differences in levels.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This is further addressed in this book’s Section 1.6.

References

  • Abraham, K. G., & Mackie, C. (2005). Beyond the market designing non-market accounts for the United States. Washington, DC: National Academies Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Albertini, M., & Kohli, M. (2012). The generational contract in the family: An analysis of transfer regimes in Europe. European Social Review (online publication).

    Google Scholar 

  • Albertini, M., Kohli, M., & Vogel, C. (2007). Intergenerational transfers of time and money in European families: Common patterns-different regimes? Journal of European Social Policy, 17, 319–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anxo, D., Flood, L., Mencarini, L., Pailhé, A., Solaz, A, & Tanturri, M. L. (2007). Time allocation between work and family over the life cycle: A comparative gender analysis of Italy, France, Sweden and the United States. IZA Discussion Paper Series No. 3193

    Google Scholar 

  • Apps, P., & Rees, R. (2005). Gender, time use, and public policy over the life cycle. IZA Discussion Papers, No.1855.

    Google Scholar 

  • Attias-Donfut, C., Ogg, J., & Wolff, F. C. (2005). European patterns of intergenerational financial and time transfers. European Journal of Ageing, 2(3), 161–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1965). A theory of the allocation of time. Economic Journal, 75(299), 493–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonsang, E. (2007). How do middle-aged children allocate time and money transfers to their older parents in Europe. Empirica, 34, 171–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brandt, M., Haberkern, K., & Szydlik, M. (2009). Intergenerational help and care in Europe. European Sociological Review, 25(5), 585–601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Da Roit, B., & Sabatinelli S. (2013). Nothing on the move or just going private? Understanding the freeze on child- and eldercare policies and the development of care markets in Italy. Social Politics, 20(3):430–453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donehower, G., & Mejía-Guevara, I. (2012). Everybody works: Gender, age, and economic activity. Paper presented at the European Population Conference, June 15, Stockholm, Sweden. Extended abstract available at http://epc2012.princeton.edu/papers/120225.

  • Fisher, K., & Gershuny, J. (2013). Multinational time use study: User’s guide and documentation. Centre for time use research. http://www.timeuse.org/files/cckpub/858/mtus-user-guide-r6-july-2013.pdf.

  • Friedman, J. H. (1984). A variable span scatterplot smoother. Laboratory for computational statistics. Stanford University. (Stanford University Tech. Rep. No. 5).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, J., Choi, S., Chatterjee, S., & Kim, H. (2012). The motivation for intergenerational time and financial transfers. Family and Consumer Sciences Research Journal, 40, 373–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohli, M. (1999). Private and public transfers between generations: Linking the family and the state. European Societies, 1, 81–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohli, M. (2004). Intergenerational transfers and inheritance: A comparative view. In M. Silverstein (Ed.), Intergenerational relations across time and place (annual review of gerontology and geriatric (Vol. 24, pp. 266–289). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets, S. (1934). National Income 1929–1932, Senate Document No. 124, 73rd Congress, 2nd Session. Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landefeld, J. S., Fraumeni, B. M., & Vojtech, C. M. (2009). Accounting for household production: A prototype satellite account using the American time use survey. Review of Income and Wealth, 55(2), 205–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, R., & Donehower, G. (2011). Private transfers in comparative perspective. In R. Lee, & A. Mason (Eds.), Population aging and the generational economy: A global perspective (pp. 185–208). Northampton: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, R., & Mason, A. (2011a). Population aging and the generational economy: Key findings. In R. Lee, & A. Mason (Eds.), Population aging and the generational economy: A global perspective (pp. 3–31). Northampton: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, R., & Mason, A. (2011b). Introduction age into national accounts. In R. Lee, & A. Mason (Eds.), Population aging and the generational economy: A global perspective (pp. 55–78). Northampton: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, R., Mason, A., Tung, A., Lai, M., & Miller, T. (2006). Population aging and intergenerational transfers: Introducing age into national accounts. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N. G., & Weil, D. N. (1989). The baby boom, the baby bust, and the housing market. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 19(2), 235–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirowsky, J., & Ross, C. (1999). Economic hardship across the life course. American Sociological Review, 64, 548–569.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Transfer Accounts. (2013). Gender, time use. http://www.ntaccounts.org/web/nta/show/Gender,%20Time%20use.

  • Phananiramai, M. (2011). Incorporating time into the national transfer accounts: The case of Thailand. In R. Lee, & A. Mason (Eds.), Population aging and the generational economy: A global perspective (pp. 528–541). Northampton: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reher, D. S. (1998). Family ties in Western Europe: Persistent contrasts. Population and Development Review, 24, 203–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reid, M. (1934). The economics of Household production. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saraceno, C., & Keck, W. (2010). Can we identify intergenerational policy regimes in Europe. European Societies, 12(5):675–695.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schenk, N., Dykstra, P., & Maas, I. (2010). The role of European welfare states in intergenerational money transfers: A micro-level perspective. Ageing & Society, 30, 1315–1342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stancanelli, E., & Van Soest, A. (2012). Retirement and home production: A regression discontinuity approach. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 102(3), 600–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • United Nations. (2013). The System of National Accounts (SNA). United Nations statistics division. http://unstats.un.org/unsd/nationalaccount/sna.asp.

  • Zagheni, E. (2011). The leverage of demographic dynamics on carbon dioxide emissions: Does age structure matter? Demography, 48(1), 371–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Emilio Zagheni .

Conclusion

Conclusion

The economic life cycle involves production, consumption, and transfers both monetary and non-monetary in scope. We discussed the need to integrate time use in the assessment of national accounts and other demographic phenomena. Intergenerational monetary transfers have long been studied, and MTUS data now allow us to analyze patterns in time production, consumption, and transfers. There are fundamental differences in how women and men, and individuals across the life cycle, experience time use and activity. We explored some of these trends for a select group of European countries.

The extent of a country’s life cycle deficits is partially determined by a country’s population age structure. Both monetary and non-monetary transfers broadly maintain these deficits. And just as trends at either end of the life cycle may exacerbate fiscal deficits by, for instance, younger individuals taking longer to enter the labor force or older individuals experiencing extended life spans, time transfer deficits may expand as well. Should they continue to grow, sustaining these life cycle deficits will require various market and non-market adaptations. The production of time could become more egalitarian between women and men in order to curtail their current imbalances. Innovative policies can be enacted to encourage increased labor force participation, at both the extensive and intensive margins, while further subsidizing childcare and eldercare, two of the most time-intensive channels of household production. Governments could consider converting some unpaid activity into paid work: recent enacted and proposed legislation in European countries would directly compensate individuals for their household work dedicated to childcare and eldercare. Other unpaid household tasks that meet the traditional third-party criterion could be relinquished to the market.

The gender gap in time production and consumption is influenced by structural, institutional, and cultural factors, and in turn, affects many other demographic processes. Fertility rates, labor market participation, and household composition respond to patterns in household time use in both underlying and proximate ways. Retirement ages differ by country; if home production on the individual and household level change significantly in response to a household’s individual or joint retirement decisions, we might expect cross-country differences in time production to be consistent with cross-country differences in pension and retirement policy. Combining data on time use for partnered households and retirement status to investigate such institutional connections is an interesting area of future research.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 The Author(s) 2015

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Zagheni, E., Zannella, M., Movsesyan, G., Wagner, B. (2015). Time is Economically Valuable: Production, Consumption and Transfers of Time by Age and Sex. In: A Comparative Analysis of European Time Transfers between Generations and Genders. SpringerBriefs in Population Studies. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-017-9591-3_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics