Skip to main content

Welfare Production and Quality of Life

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 3877 Accesses

Part of the book series: International Handbooks of Quality-of-Life ((IHQL))

Abstract

Welfare comprises much more than market income and the goods and services bought by it. Traditional indicators such as the market-based Gross Domestic Product fail to reflect this multidimensionality as they exclude household production, leisure and the use or conservation of (global) commons. Four sectors (Market-oriented private enterprises, government, households and the social economy) produce welfare. Their relative weight changes in the course of economic development and due to shifting preferences and to structural change driven by heterogeneous productivity growth. Markets are subject to crises and show severe deficits as welfare optimizers by neglecting external effects and the inequality of market participants. These deficits require a stronger role of the state which must provide a broad range of social services given the inequality of income and the relative saturation with private goods and services. Globalization can contribute to the growth and welfare of poorer countries but tends to exacerbate within-country inequality. The welfare of future generations requires not less debt, but investment in the global capital stock including education, less exploitation of planetary resources, and population control.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   389.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   499.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See also Zapf (1984) who uses the same categorization albeit replacing private corporations by “markets”. Actually, markets do not produce welfare but organize welfare production through the interaction of producers and consumers which can be any of the four types listed here.

  2. 2.

    Employment figures in this paragraph are based on Hammouya (1999).

  3. 3.

    Figures in this paragraph are taken from the 2012 Economic Freedom index of the Heritage Foundation (http://www.heritage.org/index/explore?view=by-variables)

  4. 4.

    This unusual case can probably be explained by a relatively, to the recipient’s GDP, high volume of foreign aid received by the government which allows spending to exceed GDP.

  5. 5.

    See Iversen (2005) table 1.1 on p. 16.

  6. 6.

    Destatis “Wo bleibt die Zeit? Die Zeitverwendung der Bevölkerung in Deutschland 2001/2” (http://www.bmfsfj.de/RedaktionBMFSFJ/Abteilung2/Pdf-Anlagen/wo-bleibt-zeit,property=pdf.pdf; accessed 23 July 2012).

  7. 7.

    See Flodman Becker (2004), based on ILO (International Labor Organization) statistics.

  8. 8.

    See Monzón and Chaves (2012) Chapter 4, pp. 19–21.

  9. 9.

    For a good overview see Stiglitz (2012).

  10. 10.

    In this experiment one player receives an amount of money which he must share with a second player. If both players cannot agree on the split the money will go back to the bank. Pure microeconomics suggests that the second player should accept any share as it increases his wealth. Actually the results of the experiment show that most players are willing to forego the gain if they consider the split unfair (usually meaning less than a third). Fairness is obviously valued higher than monetary gain.

  11. 11.

    Friedrich-Ebert-Foundation has commissioned several quantitative studies to analyze social growth; see Gramke et al. (2012) and Augurzky et al. (2012). A summarizing view is given in Thementeam “Soziales Wachstum” (2011).

  12. 12.

    See Iversen (2005, pp. 246–250) for a more detailed analysis of the “service economy trilemma” between equality, employment and fiscal restraint.

  13. 13.

    A life style based on local networks (including regional currencies) and homework; see Paech (2012).

  14. 14.

    http://www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr/en/index.htm (accessed 24 July 2012); see also Joseph Stiglitz, Amartya Sen und Jean Paul Fitoussi (2010).

  15. 15.

    See http://www.beyond-gdp.eu/ (accessed 24 July 2012).

  16. 16.

    See http://www.bundestag.de/bundestag/ausschuesse17/gremien/enquete/wachstum/index.jsp (accessed 24 July 2012).

  17. 17.

    see Dauderstädt and Keltek (2011) based on the World Inequality Database (http://www.wider.unu.edu/research/Database/en_GB/wiid/).

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael Dauderstädt .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Dauderstädt, M. (2015). Welfare Production and Quality of Life. In: Glatzer, W., Camfield, L., Møller, V., Rojas, M. (eds) Global Handbook of Quality of Life. International Handbooks of Quality-of-Life. Springer, Dordrecht. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-017-9178-6_17

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics